Social capital: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 40: Line 40:


==Political implications==
==Political implications==
An early exponent of the political implications of social capital was the 19th century political historian Alexis de Tocqueville. After a visit to America he wrote with approval of the practice there of the "art of association":
:"When the public govern, there is no man who does not feel the value of public goodwill or who does not endeavor to court it by drawing to himself the esteem and affection of those among whom he is to live.... Men learn at such times to think of their fellow men from ambitious motives; and they frequently find it, in a manner, their interest to forget themselves"<ref>[http://xroads.virginia.edu/~Hyper/DETOC/toc_indx.html Alexis de Tocqueville: ''Democracy in America'', ]</ref>.


==Economic implications==
==Economic implications==

Revision as of 06:31, 4 January 2010

This article has a Citable Version.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable Main Article has an approved citable version (see its Citable Version subpage). While we have done conscientious work, we cannot guarantee that this Main Article, or its citable version, is wholly free of mistakes. By helping to improve this editable Main Article, you will help the process of generating a new, improved citable version.

Social capital is an interdisciplinary social science concept that has been used to bring together aspects of social conduct, such as trust and cooperation, that may be expected to contribute to the well-being of a community. There have been attempts to quantify its influence upon community achievements, but there is no agreement concerning the weights that should be assigned to its components, and there have been reservations about the validity of any attempt to aggregate them.

Definition and implications

Though it was invoked by several political economists during the late nineteenth century and used in passing by John Dewey in 1900, the term "social capital" was first used extensively by L.J. Hanifan in his 1916 and 1920 studies of the rural community center.[1] In the latter, he defined social capital as "that in life which tends to make ... tangible substances count for most in the daily lives of a people; namely, good will, fellowship, sympathy, and social intercourse among the individuals and families who make up a social unit."[2] He further proposed that, just as financial capital must be amassed before a construction project can commence, social capital must be accummulated in order for meaningful community building to take place.[3]

Hanifan's contribution went unrecognized for many years and, as Robert Putnam notes, the concept of "social capital" was subsequently "independently invented" at least five more times.[4] In Foundations of Social Theory, for example, the sociologist James Coleman credits the term to Glenn Loury, an economist who in 1977 defined social capital as a set of designated intangible resources in families and communities that help to promote the social development of young people.[5] Loury himself has attributed it to Jane Jacobs, an urban planner who used the term metaphorically in her 1961 book, The Death and Life of Great American Cities.[6]

There are many definitions of social capital in social and political science. One widely accepted version defines it as an “investment in social relations with expected returns in the marketplace.”[7] This definition is consistent with interpretations by Pierre Bourdieu, Nan Lin, James Coleman, Hendrik Flap, Ronald Burt, Robert Putnam, Jenny Onyx, Bonnie Erickson and others; nevertheless, it remains a matter of controversy, as noted in the concluding section of this article. The sociologist Pierre Bourdieu defined the concept as “the aggregate of the actual or potential resources which are linked to possession of a durable network of more or less institutionalized relationships of mutual acquaintance or recognition” [8]. He pointed out that “Social capital is the sum of the resources, actual and virtual, that accrue to an individual or a group by virtue of possessing a durable network of more or less institutionalized relationships of mutual acquaintances and recognition.”[9] Francis Fukuyama defined it as "a capability that arises from the prevalence of trust in a society." [10] James Coleman defined social capital “as a variety of entities with two elements in common: They all consist of some aspect of social structure, and they facilitate certain action of actors-whether persons or corporate actors-within the structure.”[11] To be capital a social structure must serve a function for individuals engaged in an activity. The actors exercise control over the resources in which they have an interest and at least partial control of others involved. Social relations are important to facilitating this action by the actors.

The concept of social capital can be related to similar concepts of civil society that are drawn from the works of James Madison (in The Federalist Papers), Alexis de Tocqueville (in Democracy in America) and John Stuart Mill (in On Liberty).

The creation of social capital

The creation of social capital has been analysed as a personal investment and as a community investment. As a personal investment it has been taken to include social skills, charisma, and a networks of contacts, all of which can be used as a personal means of obtaining an economic return from interactions with others. A study combining empirical evidence with the predictions of an economic model of the personal investment decision[12] has indicated, among other findings, that higher levels of investment are made by people who also invest in other aspects of human capital. As a community investment, it has been suggested that it is created by the process termed emergence by which a complex interactive system[13] can transform itself from chaos to order. The initial position is taken to be similar to the "state of nature" envisaged by Thomas Hobbes in which there is a constant "war of all against all". That condition is taken to be analagous to the prisoner's dilemma parable [14] of game theory, in which both participants suffer unnecessarily because neither trusts the other. Computer simulations have demonstrated that when the two protagonists interact repeatedly they can develop a mutually beneficial evolutionary stable strategy that once is established is likely to persist[15]. Case studies and experiments with human participants[16] show that mutually beneficial strategies involving trust do emerge spontaneously and that when they do, their stability often tends to be promoted by an urge to punish defectors.

Social capital can then emerge in the form of expectations that others will reciprocate in response to co-operative initiatives; and it can spread through the community as more and more people become aware of the advantages of cooperation, and Charles Darwin has suggested that it could be transmitted further by natural selection:

"A tribe including many members who, from possessing in a high degree the spirit of patriotism, fidelity, obedience, courage,and sympathy, were always ready to aid one another, and to sacrifice themselves for the common good, would be victorious over most other tribes; and this would be natural selection[17]

The components of social capital

Organizational components

Although they are interrelated, it is customary to distinguish the influence of a community's social organization on the social acts of its members from its influence on their individual attitudes. A community's social capital is generally considered to be determined as much by the collective traditions, beliefs and value systems that are part of its culture, as by the cognitive characteristics and perceptions of its members. Similarly, the collectively-determined rules embodied in a community’s institutions, are considered to be as necessary to the development of social capital as the impulses and constraints created by the psychological drives that are experienced by its members. The institutions that are held to be capable of contributing to social capital range from the state apparatus of law-making and enforcement, to the patterns of mutual obligation that are created by interpersonal networks. Interpersonal networks have been categorized by applying the terms "bonding", "bridging" and "linking" to, respectively, networks of family and friends; networks of colleagues and associates; and networks that connect different networks.

Cognitive components

Social influences are considered to provide the principal components of people's social attitudes. Trust, for example, is considered to be influenced mainly by the social institutions that have been referred to. However, there is evidence to suggest that a significant component may also come from the innate or “hard-wired” characteristics of the human brain. Neuroeconomics experiments [18] have revealed an association between the possession of a particular hormone and a propensity to trust others [19].) Trust in the sense of believing most people to be trustworthy is referred to in the literature as "generalized trust" to distinguish it from trust in particular categories of people and trust concerning specific issues. Unsurprisingly, it has been found to be highest in communities where there are effective institutions that punish cheats; but it has also been found to be positively associated with education, civil liberties, and ease of communication (roads and telephones) and negatively associated with ethnic diversity and income inequality. Trust is generally held to be an essential component of social capital, as is willingness to conform to collectively-determined rules, but other cognitive characteristics have often been been included: notably the willingness to take actions that are for the exclusive benefit of others. Examples include charitable donations, participation in voluntary collective activities, and many other forms of philanthropy. The exercise of such social attitudes has been held to be among the main characteristics of civil society. Beyond those essentials, however, attitudes that are generally conducive to social concord such as tolerance of unfamiliar customs, practices and beliefs and a general preference for negotiation over confrontation have sometimes been included.

Sociological Implications

It has been established by a variety of studies that social capital has a direct effect upon the well-being of members of a community in addition to the indirect effects that arise from its economic consequences [20]. The connection between social capital and individual well-being has been used to explain the fact that, in many countries, and despite growing prosperity, subjectively – reported well being has not increased over the years – an observation that is often referred to as the “happiness paradox”. The connection has been attributed to the psychological importance of interpersonal relationships [21] and the decline in happiness in the United States has been related to measures of “relational social capital” [22].

Other studies have examined social capital's effects upon health, longevity, suicide rates and the incidence of crime. In a study sponsored by Britain’s National Health Service, low levels of survey-determined neighborhood attachment were found to be associated with higher risks of mental illness and marital breakdown [23]. A study of crime among homeless youths in Toronto and Vancouver established strong associations with social capital[24]. However, it was found from a cross-country study sponsored by the World Bank that the only component of social capital that was negatively associated with the incidence of murder, was trust among community members [25].

Political implications

An early exponent of the political implications of social capital was the 19th century political historian Alexis de Tocqueville. After a visit to America he wrote with approval of the practice there of the "art of association":

"When the public govern, there is no man who does not feel the value of public goodwill or who does not endeavor to court it by drawing to himself the esteem and affection of those among whom he is to live.... Men learn at such times to think of their fellow men from ambitious motives; and they frequently find it, in a manner, their interest to forget themselves"[26].

Economic implications

Economists were writing about social capital before that term came into use. Writing in 1891, Alfred Marshall referred to economics as “a branch of biology, interpreted broadly” and attributed differences between successful and unsuccessful economic activity to variations in "general enlightenment ... and habits of mutual trust", and in the willingness of people to “sacrifice themselves for the common wellbeing” [27]. Similar statements have been attributed to Thorstein Veblen, writing at about the same time. Some eighty years later the economist Kenneth Arrow remarked that much of the economic backwardness in the world could be explained as "lack of mutual confidence" [28]. Until recently, however, social capital had been regarded as merely an exogenous factor that is necessary to a reasonable standard of economic efficiency in much the same way as a functioning monetary system; and little attention had been given to its creation or to its quantitative influence. The idea that collective action might be expected to promote economic performance had been specifically rejected in the writings of the economist Mancur Olson (whose views are summarised below under the heading objections and qualifications)

Interest in the quantitative effects of social capital was stimulated by Robert Putnam’s 1993 study of democracy in Italy, in which he attributed the higher levels of GDP per capita in the North to previously higher levels of civic engagement, his measure of which gave weight to membership of voluntary organizations (which he referred to as "horizontal ties") [29]; and later by his essay and best-selling book, "Bowling Alone" [30], in which he attached importance to the decline in membership of voluntary organizations in the United States, (of which he took the decline in membership of bowling clubs to be a typical example). Apparently prompted by Putnam's Italian study, several further examinations of the economic effects of various components of social capital have since been reported. A 1997 study using data collected by the World Bank for a sample of 29 market economies established a statistical association between economic performance and measures of trust and civic cooperation, but did not confirm Putnam's finding about the importance of horizontal ties[31]. In a survey of economic growth studies by Robert Barro [32] several components of social capital emerge as making significant contributions, notably education, the maintenance of law and the strength of democratic institutions.

Policy implications

The economist Partha Dasgupta has argued that a personal investment in a reputation for trustworthiness results in beneficial “externalities”: that is to say benefits to others besides the person who makes the investment [33]. It is a generally accepted proposition of economic theory that markets tend to underprovide activities that generate beneficial externalities, and that it is to the benefit of the community for governments to make up the deficiency. That proposition has been extended to suggest that economic welfare can be increased by government intervention in the provision of many of the components of social capital, and has led to a variety of policy studies. A range of policy proposals has been put forward by the Saguaro Seminar in the United States [34], and a research paper by Australia’s Productivity Commission lists some possible policy initiatives to promote social capital, some side-effects of existing policies, and some policies that already make use of the existing stock of social capital [35]. Although potentially beneficial policies can be readily identified, the problem of quantifying the benefits of specific interventions, to enable them to be subjected to cost/benefit assessments, remains an obstacle to the formulation of policies that can be expected to yield net benefits.

Measuring social capital

Measurements of the components of social capital have been undertaken by social researchers in many different countries.[36] In the United States, the Social Community Benchmark Survey was a telephone survey of over 30,000 respondents conducted by a network of researchers in 40 communities in the year 2000.[37]. It was followed up in 2006 by a further selective survey [38] As of the beginning of 2008, over 50 studies have used the Social Benchmark Survey data.[39] The European Union’s Active Citizen Composite Index combines 63 basic indicators, drawn mainly from the European Social Survey into a single index by an arbitrary weighting regime. Composite indexes are also produced concerning the variously-defined topics of social cohesion, civil society, community cohesion, political life , human development, and corruption perceptions.[40] The World Bank’s Social Capital Assessment Tool gathers information by survey and interview as source data for the assessment of social capital. [41]. Surveys conducted by national statistics agencies provide a further source of relevant statistics. British statistical surveys containing a social capital element have been listed by their Office of National Statistics [42]

The problem of combining measures of the various components of social capital into a single index number has been tackled by a number of researchers [43], but as Francis Fukuyama has noted, there is no consensus as to how it should be done [44]. Robert Putnam combined 13 different measures into a single measure, using factor analysis – a technique that establishes weights related to evidence concerning the effects of each component upon a chosen outcome [45]. Other attempts have been criticized on the grounds that invalid econometrics methods were used [46].

Objections and qualifications

There is no single consensus approach to social capital. Many of the disputes are interdisciplinary, with economists, sociologists and political scientists often disagreeing about discrete points. There have been objections to Robert Putnam’s approach, for example, on the grounds that it is logically inconsistent. Michael Woolcock has argued that to avoid tautological reasoning, any definition of social capital should focus on its sources rather than its consequences, or "what it is, not what it does."[47] In other words, if social capital is defined as a contributor to an outcome, it would be tautological to claim that it contributes to that outcome. Studies that relate single components of social capital to the outcome under investigation are not affected by that objection, but it raises doubts about the use of combinations of components, members of which are included because of their expected contributions to that outcome. There have also been objections to the aggregation of organizational and cognitive components where the two categories are inter-related (since trust is promoted by law enforcement, a weighted sum those two components is difficult to interpret). Also, Portes and Landolt have questioned the assumption that a community’s social capital is the sum of that of its members [48], as well as the assumption that its outcomes are necessarily beneficial to the community - recalling Mancur Olson’s suggestion that the principle motive for the formation of an association is rent-seeking [49] - in other words, an attempt by a group to gain an advantage at the expense of the community. (The assumption that social capital necessarily benefits even those groups that acquire it is contrary to the evidence of the “Robbers Cave Experiments”, which demonstrated that close-knit groups tend to acquire dangerously mistaken perceptions concerning their members and others [50].) James de Fillipis has described Robert Putnam’s methodology as "fundamentally flawed" and has argued for a return to the interpretation of the concept by Pierre Bourdieu [51] as being essentially about the power to attract and control physical capital [52]

References

  1. Hanifan, L. J. (1916) "The rural school community center," Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 67: 130-138; Hanifan, L. J. (1920)The Community Center. Boston: Silver, Burdett. On the significance of the concept's usage pre-Hanifan, see James Farr, "Social Capital: A Conceptual History," Political Theory 32:1 (2004) pp. 6-22.
  2. Hanifan (1920) p. 78.
  3. Ibid.
  4. Robert D. Putnam, Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community (New York: Simon and Schuster, 2001) p. 19.
  5. James S. Coleman. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, p. 300; see also Loury, Glenn C. 1977. "A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences", In Women Minorities and Employment Discrimination, ed P.A. Wallace. Lexington MA. Health
  6. Glen C. Loury, "The Neumann Lecture," presented at Rajk László College, Corvinus University of Economic Science and Public Administration, Budapest, Hungary, September 30. 3005; full text available at [1]. See also Jane Jacobs (1961) The Death and Life of Great American Cities. New York: Vintage, p. 138.
  7. Nan Lin: Social Capital; A Theory of Social Structure and Action. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2001.
  8. Pierre Bourdieu and Loic Wacquant: 1992. An Invitation to Reflexive Sociology, Chicago, University of Chicago Press 1992.
  9. Pierre Bourdieu, "The forms of Capital" in Handbook of Theory and Research for the Sociology of Education, ed. JG Richardson. New York, Greenwood 1985.
  10. Francis Fukuyama: Trust: The Social Virtues of the Creation of Prosperity. Free Press Paperbacks Simon and Schuster, 1996, p. 26.
  11. James Coleman: "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital", American Journal of Sociology. 94:S95-121 1988.
  12. Edward Glaeser, David Laibson and Bruce Sacerdotum: "An Economic Approach to Social Capital", The Economic Journal November 2002
  13. defined at [2]
  14. defined at [3]
  15. Robert Axelrod:The Evolution of Cooperation, Basic Books, 1984
  16. Joyce Berg, John Dickhaut and Kevin McCabe Trust, Recprocity and Social History, Games and Economic Behaviour 10, 1995
  17. Charles Darwin: The Ascent of Man, Chapter V, (first published 1874) Project Gutenberg
  18. Paul Zak: Neuroeconomics The Royal Society “6th November 2004
  19. Paul Zak: The Neuroeconomics of Trust Loma Linda University Medical Center
  20. Studies of the social effects of social capital are surveyed in John Helliwell: "Social Capital, the Economy and Well-Being" in The Review of Economic Performance and Social Progress, 2001, page 43
  21. Maurizio Pugno: The Happiness Paradox – A Formal Explanation from Psycho-economics, December 2004
  22. Maurizio Pugno et al: Did the Decline in Social Capital Decrease American Happiness? May 2007
  23. David Pevalin : "Intra-household Differences in Neighbourhood Attachment and their Association with Health" Chapter 5 of - Antony Morgan and Catherine Swann (eds): Social Capital for Health: Issues of Definition, Measurement and Links to Health, Health Development Agency , National Health Service, March 2004
  24. John Hagan and Bill McCarthy: Mean Streets: Youth Crime and Homelessness. Cambridge University Press. 1998
  25. Daniel Lederman, Norman Loayza and Ana Menendez: Violent Crime: Does Social Capital Matter?. World Bank, July 2000
  26. Alexis de Tocqueville: Democracy in America,
  27. Alfred Marshall: "The Scope and Method of Economics" , Appendix C of Principles of Economics, Macmillan 1964
  28. Kenneth Arrow "Gifts and Exchanges" in Philosophy and Public Affairs Vol. 1, No. 4 1972 p 357
  29. Robert Putnam: Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Northern Italy, Princeton University Press, 1993
  30. Robert Putnam Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community Simon and Schuster 2000)
  31. Stephen Knack and Phillip Keever: "Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff? A Cross-country Investigation", Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 4 1997
  32. Robert Barro: Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study, (Lionel Robbins Lectures) MIT Press, 1997
  33. Partha Dasgupta: "Social Capital and Economic Performance : Analytics" in Elinor Ostrom and TK Ahn (eds): Foundations of Social Capital, Critical Writings in Economic Institutions, Edward Elgar 2003.
  34. Social Capital a Discussion Paper Table 13 p56, UK Performance and Innovation Unit, April 2002
  35. Social Capital: Reviewing the Concept and its Policy Implications, pages 55-66, Productivity Commission Research Paper, Commonwealth of Australia, 2003
  36. For an account of the methods used to measure the components of social capital in different countries see Sandra Franke: Measurement of Social Capital. Reference document for public policy research. Policy Research Initiative, Government of Canada, September 2005
  37. The Social Community Benchmark Survey 2000
  38. The 2006 Social Community Survey
  39. List of studies using the SCBS data
  40. Bryony Hoskins et al: Measuring Active Citizenship in Europe, European Commission Joint Research Centre, CRELL Research Paper 6, 2006
  41. Anirudh Krishna and Elizabeth Shrader: Social Capital Assessment Tool, World Bank, 1999
  42. Dave Ruston: "Matrix of United Kingdom Surveys with a Social Element", Appendix 2 of Social Capital: A Review of the Literature, Social Analysis and Reporting Division Office of National Statistics, October 2001
  43. For example Paul Bullen and Jenny Onyx: Social Capital: The Measurement Tool, Conference Abstract, International Society for Third Sector Research 2006
  44. Francis Fukuyama: "Social Capital, Civil Society and Development" page 12, Third World Quarterly, 2001
  45. Robert Putnam: "Social Capital: Measurement and Consequences", in Proceedings of OECD/HRDC Conference, 2001
  46. Stephen Durlauf: On the Empirics of Social Capital, 2002
  47. Michael Woolcock: "The Place of Social Capital in Understanding Social and Economic Outcomes", Canadian Journal of Policy Research 2(1), 2001
  48. Alejandro Portes and Patricia Landolt: "The Downside of Social Capital", The American Prospect May/June 1996
  49. Mancur Olson: The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Harvard University Press, 1971
  50. Muzafer Sherif, O. J. Harvey, Jack White, William Hood and Carolyn Sherif: Intergroup Conflict and Cooperation: The Robbers Cave Experiments, Oklahoma University Book Exchange, 1961
  51. Pierre Bourdieu and Loic Wacquant: An Invitation to Reflexive Sociology, University of Chicago Press, 1992.
  52. James De Fillippis: "The Myth of Social Capital in Community Development", Housing Policy Debate Vol 12 Issue 4, The Fanny Mae Foundation, 2001 [4]