Law of diminishing returns: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Paul Schächterle
imported>Caesar Schinas
m (Bot: Update image code)
Line 17: Line 17:


==The neoclassical concept==
==The neoclassical concept==
[[Image:Production function with decreasing returns to scale.png|thumb|right|300px|Production function (blue) with decreasing returns to scale (green) and therefore decreasing average returns (magenta).]]
{{Image|Production function with decreasing returns to scale.png|right|300px|Production function (blue) with decreasing returns to scale (green) and therefore decreasing average returns (magenta).}}
In [[History of economic thought#Neoclassical_Economics|neoclassical economics]] the LDR signifies that an increasing input of ''any'' production factor will result in diminishing marginal productivity. This leads to a production function with the following characteristics:
In [[History of economic thought#Neoclassical_Economics|neoclassical economics]] the LDR signifies that an increasing input of ''any'' production factor will result in diminishing marginal productivity. This leads to a production function with the following characteristics:
* Zero input of a production factor results in zero output i.e. the graph starts at the [[Origin (Mathematics)|origin]].
* Zero input of a production factor results in zero output i.e. the graph starts at the [[Origin (Mathematics)|origin]].

Revision as of 04:44, 8 June 2009

This article is developing and not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.

The law of diminishing returns (in this article referred to as LDR) is a concept in economic theory. It states that the output per input (productivity) declines if the input of a production factor is increased over a certain limit. Under the name law of diminishing returns actually exist two different concepts: one classical and one neoclassical. These concepts bear similarities but are based on different reasons.

The classical concept

Production function (blue) with first rising and then diminishing marginal (green) and average (magenta) returns.

In classical economics the LDR states the following: If you have at least two different production factors, the highest productivity is gained if an optimal proportion between these factors is kept. Any divergence from that proportion will result in lower productivity.

If one production factor is fixed, the proportion between the production factors will change with rising production i.e. rising input of the variable factor. According to the classical LDR this leads to a production function that has four phases with the following characteristics:

  1. Rising marginal productivity, rising average productivity.
  2. Diminishing marginal productivity, rising average productivity.
  3. Diminishing average productivity.
  4. Negative marginal productivity, i.e. an increase of the variable factor will result in a decrease of the overall product.

History

Historically the concept was first developed by Anne Robert Jacques Turgot. It was mainly related to agricultural production and the use of labour and later fertilizer in relation to a fixed amount of soil.[1]

The neoclassical concept

(CC) Image: Paul Schächterle
Production function (blue) with decreasing returns to scale (green) and therefore decreasing average returns (magenta).

In neoclassical economics the LDR signifies that an increasing input of any production factor will result in diminishing marginal productivity. This leads to a production function with the following characteristics:

  • Zero input of a production factor results in zero output i.e. the graph starts at the origin.
  • Marginal productivity is highest with the lowest possible input, i.e. the point closest to an input of zero.
  • Marginal productivity decreases continuously.

History

The origins of the neoclassical production function i.e. the neoclassical LDR date back to the time of classical economics. Then the concept was used to describe the effect of an increase in wheat production where good soils were limited. To increase the production of wheat inferior soils would have to be used, which would deliver less wheat for the same amount of labour.[2]

Neoclassical economists extended the idea to the claim that any economically rational producer would use any production factor first for the most productive task, then for the next productive task, etc., and/or would use the best unit first, then the second best, etc. Thus the idea got applied to all production factors.

Implications

The general validity of the neoclassical LDR is a necessary condition for the existence of a stable equilibrium in the General Equilibrium Theory (production sets must be convex).

Critique

The argumentation on which the neoclassical LDR is based assumes that there are units of a factor with different quality and/or there are fields of application of the factor with different productivity.[3]

Combining both concepts

Cobb-Douglas production function with 2 factors and production elasticity complying to the neoclassical LDR, i.e. overall decreasing returns to scale.

Neoclassical theory usually distinguishes between only two factors of production: capital and labour. With just two factors of production the production function can be represented by a 3-dimensional graph.

Tho most prominent production function for creating such a graph is the Cobb-Douglas production function: Y = A × Ca × Lb, where Y stands for yield, C for capital, L for labour, and A, a and b are constants that can be interpreted as A for technology level and a and b for the production elasticities of the factors. This formula can contain elements of both concepts, the classical and the neoclassical LDR.

The classical concept is represented by the fact that a combination of both factors results in a square output so that an even proportion between the factors results in higher productivity.

The neoclassical concept is represented by the fact that each factor has diminishing returns to scale as long as (a < 1) and (b < 1). Note that the combined input of both factors only results in diminishing returns as long as (a + b < 1). If both factors independently have decreasing returns to scale (a < 1, b < 1), their combination might still lead to increasing returns to scale (a + b > 1).

For an interactive demonstration of the Cobb-Douglas production function see: [1]

Naming conventions

Viewing their attributed originators the names for both concepts may seem misleading. Turgot is considered physiocrat, not classical economist, and Ricardo is considered classical, not neoclassical economist. Yet the names of both concepts reflect the eras of their further development and refinement.

References

  1. Turgot, Observations sur le mémoire de M. de Saint-Péravy en faveur de l’impôt indirect, 1768. In: Turgot, Anne Robert Jacques (1727—1781), Oeuvres de Turgot, 1966, pp. 418 sqq., (421), Gallica, Bibliothèque nationale de France
  2. David Ricardo, 1772—1823, An Essay on Profits, 1815
  3. Felderer/Homburg, Makroökonomik und neue Makroökonomik, S. 55, Fn. 4