IS-LM model: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
m (Text replacement - "markets" to "market (economics)")
 
(20 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Subpages}}
{{Subpages}}
The  '''IS-LM model''' is used in the teaching of [[macroeconomics]] to depict  the interaction of the factors determining the level of demand in an economy.  
{|align="center" cellpadding="5" style="background:lightgray; width:95%; border: 1px solid #aaa; margin:10px; font-size: 92%;"
| There is  a [[/Tutorials|'''mathematical supplement ''']] to this article on the tutorials subpage.
|}
The  '''IS-LM model''' is used in the teaching of [[macroeconomics]] to depict  the interaction of the factors determining the level of demand in an economy.


==The Model==
==The Model==
===The two markets===
The IS-LM model conceptualises the economy as consisting of two  [[market (economics)|market]] in one of which occurs all of the purchases of goods and services that happen throughout the country and in the other of which occurs all of the purchases of financial assets.  It shows how a country's national income  may be jointly  determined by the way people behave in the market for goods and services and the way they behave in the market for financial assets. In the market for goods, investment is taken to be the active element,  with consumption being determined passively as what remains of national income after deducting what is assumed to be the  more-or-less fixed proportion  that goes into saving. The financial assets market  is taken  to be made up on the one hand of money, which is non-interest-bearing, and on the other of all of those assets (such as stocks, bonds and savings certificates) which, in one way or another, can be considered to be  interest-bearing. The cost of holding money rather than interest-bearing assets is taken to be the interest payments that are thereby foregone, but people are taken to wish to hold a certain amount of money for day-to-day transactions.
[[Image:ISLM.png|right|250px]]
[[Image:ISLM.png|right|250px]]


The IS-LM model describes a way  in which a country's national income  might be jointly determined by the way in which their income and the available interest rates are related to people's  preference as between saving and spending (their  "propensity to save"), and by the way in which those factors are related to their wish to hold a stock of money in the form of cash (their "liquidity-preference").
===Model structure===
In its graphical form the model is shown as a pair of intersecting curves relating the level of national income (on the horizontal axis) to the rate of interest (on the vertical axis).  
In its graphical form the model is shown as a pair of intersecting curves relating the level of national income (on the horizontal axis) to the rate of interest (on the vertical axis).  
* The I-S (investment-savings) curve depicts those combinations of interest rate and income that are consistent with the equality of investment and saving.
* The I-S (investment-savings) curve depicts those combinations of interest rate and income that are consistent with the equality of investment and saving.
* The L-M (liquidity-money supply) curve shows, those combinations of interest rate and income that make the public just willing to hold a given quantity of money.
* The L-M (liquidity-money supply) curve shows, those combinations of interest rate and income that make the public just willing to hold a given quantity of money.


== History ==
The shape of the I-S curve follows from the fact that a rise in interest rates tends to encourage saving and discourage investment, combined with  the assumption that the amount that people save rises and falls with income in an unchanging relationship (termed the "propensity to save").  Then for saving to be kept in line with investment, a rise in the interest rate must be accompanied by  fall in income so that the resulting  fall in investment is accompanied by the balancing fall in saving. Conversely, a fall in the interest rate would be associated with an increase in income. So the I-S curve has to fall from left to right.
=== Creation and rise ===


The IS-LM model creation is directly linked with the proposal by John Maynard Keynes of alternative assumptions to what classical economics assumed until then and seemed unable to explain the [[great depression]]. The main innovations in the ''General Theory'' were that prices were considered as rigid and money could be demanded for itself as an alternative to financial assets. Under those assumptions, the economy can be in equilibrium with a high level of unemployment whereas classical economics assumes that unemployment was regulated by variation in wages.  
The shape of the L-M curve reflects two assumptions, one being the assumption that the quantity of money that the public wishes to hold in order to have it available for speculation falls as the interest rate rises, and the other being the assumption that the amount of money that is tied up in day-to-day transactions rises with a rise in national income. It follows  from those assumptions that, at a given level of the total [[money supply]], the process of reconciling the transactions demand with the speculative demand implies a positive association between national income and the rate of interest. So the L-M curve has to rise from left to right.  


In 1937, John Hicks built the IS-LM model in order to translate those ideas in neoclassical terms<ref>Hicks, J. R. (1937), "Mr. Keynes and the Classics - A Suggested Interpretation", ''Econometrica''</ref>. Some Keynesians saw his attempt as a simplification of Keynes vision but Keynes approved it.  
The way in which the model explains  the tendency for the economy to settle down to an [[economic equilibrium|equilibrium]] following a shock or a sudden change in behaviour,  can be examined in words by supposing that there is a reduction in the public's propensity to save, meaning that people spend more of their money on "consumption goods". That would prompt an increase in the supply of those goods, in the total income of those employed  in their production, and thus an increase in national income. However, that increase in expenditure and income would mean that more of the available money would be used as "transactions balances" reducing the amount available for  people to hold as cash reserves for speculative purposes. That would make people  willing to pay more in interest to restore their speculative reserves and the resulting rise in interest rates would stimulate saving and discourage investment and so check the growth in income. The implied assumption is that those adjustments take place instantaneously and without regard for expected developments.


The model summarized Keynes ideas in two curves. IS represented the equality between supply and demand in the goods and services market. The aggregate demand included consumption and investment. In the ''General Theory'', consumption was a proportion of the income, called propensity to consume, while investment was related to interest rates. Variations of investment and consumption were amplified by the propensity to consume ([[spending multiplier]]). On the side of the monetary market, demand for money included speculative demand related to the interest rate and transactions demand related to the output while supply was controlled by the monetary authority.
===Interpretation===
The model is widely used in the teaching of economics to discuss the relative effectiveness of [[fiscal policy]] and [[monetary policy]] as means of stabilising the economy.  


The model demonstrated that under those assumptions, monetary and fiscal authorities could have a powerful influence on economic activity and thus reduce unemployment. It also provides a tool to understand and predict the effects of Keynesian policies. The IS-LM model knew the same future than Keynesian economics: rise and then decline.
The effect of using fiscal policy in the form of an increase in [[public expenditure]], as represented as the effect of a shift to the right of the I-S curve, is to produce an additional rise of national income, the magnitude of which depends upon the slope of the L-M curve at the point of intersection - the steeper it is, the smaller will be the additional increase in national income. The steepness of the L-M curve depends, in turn on two factors:
* the ''income elasticity of the demand for money'', (meaning the extent to which the demand for money for to finance transactions increases in response to a change in national income). The higher is the income elasticity, the  greater will be the interest rate increase need to bring the supply of money into equality with its supply and so the steeper will be the L-M curve.
* the ''interest elasticity of demand for money'' (meaning the extent to which the demand for money falls in response to an increase in interest rates).
The higher is the interest elasticity, the flatter will be the L-M curve.
 
The effect of using monetary policy by increasing the [[money supply]], as represented by a move to the right of the L-M curve, is to increase national income to an extent that depends upon the slope of the I-S curve at the point of intersection - the steeper is the I-S curve, the smaller will be the increase in national income. The slope of the I-S curve depends in turn upon:-
* the ''interest elasticity of investment'' (meaning the response of investment to a change of interest rates). The higher is that elasticity, the larger will be the increase in national income in response to a fall in interest rate so the flatter will be the I-S curve.
 
== The history of the model==
The model was first put forward in a 1937 lecture by Sir John Hicks, who presented it then as a way of illustrating the relationship between the [[Keynesian theory]] of [[macroeconomics]] and the previously orthodox "classical theory"
<ref>Hicks, J. R. (1937), "Mr. Keynes and the Classics - A Suggested Interpretation", ''Econometrica''[http://bbs.cenet.org.cn/uploadImages/20037191455699785.pdf]</ref>.


An important extension of the IS-LM model was built by Robert Mundell (1963) and Marcus Fleming (1962) in the 1960's. The [[Mundell-Fleming model]] describes a small open economy with one more curve representing equilibriums of international exchanges.
An important extension of the IS-LM model was built by Robert Mundell (1963) and Marcus Fleming (1962) in the 1960's. The [[Mundell-Fleming model]] describes a small open economy with one more curve representing equilibriums of international exchanges.


=== Decline ===
==The limitations of the model==
 
During the 1950’s and 1960’s microeconomic investigations on consumption and investment gave a better understanding of the IS slope. [[Milton Friedman]] developed the idea that the consumption level of household’s was mainly determined by a long-term expectation a theory known as the [[permanent income hypothesis]]<ref>Friedman, Milton (1957). A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton Univ Press.</ref>. [[Franco Modigliani]] [[life-cycle theory]] demonstrated that consumption was also related to age. Those two theories denied short-term policies to have an important effect on consumption, and thus the effects of the [[spending multiplier]].
During the 1950’s and 1960’s microeconomic investigations on consumption and investment gave a better understanding of the IS slope. [[Milton Friedman]] developed the idea that the consumption level of household’s was mainly determined by a long-term expectation a theory known as the [[permanent income hypothesis]]<ref>Friedman, Milton (1957). A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton Univ Press.</ref>. [[Franco Modigliani]] [[life-cycle theory]] demonstrated that consumption was also related to age. Those two theories denied short-term policies to have an important effect on consumption, and thus the effects of the [[spending multiplier]].


Such criticisms of keynesian ideas were not always criticisms of the IS/LM model. In fact, economists like Milton Friedman used the IS/LM framework to confute Keynesian economics<ref>Bordo, Michael D. & Schwartz, Anna J. (2003), "IS-LM and Monetarism", National Bureau of Economic Research, p.18 [http://www.econ.ucdavis.edu/faculty/kdhoover/pdf/Hope/Bordo%20and%20Schwartz.pdf]</ref>. Yet Friedman rejected the paradigm of "general equilibrium" he viewed as characterized by "abstractness, generality, and mathematical elegance"<ref>Milton Friedman (1949 (1953)), , "The Marshallian Demand Curve" in ''Essays in Positive Economics'', Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, pp. 47-99.</ref>  
Such criticisms of Keynesian ideas were not always criticisms of the IS/LM model. In fact, economists like Milton Friedman used the IS/LM framework to confute Keynesian economics<ref>Bordo, Michael D. & Schwartz, Anna J. (2003), "IS-LM and Monetarism", National Bureau of Economic Research, p.18 [http://www.econ.ucdavis.edu/faculty/kdhoover/pdf/Hope/Bordo%20and%20Schwartz.pdf]</ref>. Yet Friedman rejected the paradigm of "general equilibrium" he viewed as characterized by "abstractness, generality, and mathematical elegance"<ref>Milton Friedman (1949 (1953)), , "The Marshallian Demand Curve" in ''Essays in Positive Economics'', Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, pp. 47-99.</ref>  
 
The most severe criticisms of the IS/LM model came from the fact that it negligees private agents expectations. Modern macroeconomic models which take expectations into accounts can provide results opposite to those of IS/LM.  In fact, the model considers that short run is independent from long run. Yet expectations about the future have for example a direct impact on current wages which stimulates inflation and thus cancelled the positive effects of many macroeconomic policies described by the IS/LM model. In such cases, inflation remains the only effect and disturbs the coordination of private agents. The consequence of the rational expectations theory is that central banks of several industrial countries (the [[Federal Reserve]] and the [[European Central Bank]] for example) have been given independency and inflation control as their main objective.
 
=== Nowadays ===


Nowadays IS/LM model is an obsolete tool : its neglect of expectations makes it inefficient to implement an efficient economic policy. Yet, along with its Mundell-Fleming extension, it remains the most common macroeconomic model taught to undergraduate students because of its pedagogical qualities.
The most severe criticisms of the IS/LM model came from the fact that it neglects private agents' expectations. Modern macroeconomic models which take expectations into accounts can provide results opposite to those of IS/LM.  In fact, the model considers that short run is independent from long run. Yet expectations about the future have for example a direct impact on current wages which stimulates inflation and thus cancelled the positive effects of many macroeconomic policies described by the IS/LM model. In such cases, inflation remains the only effect and disturbs the coordination of private agents. The consequence of the rational expectations theory is that central banks of several industrial countries (the [[Federal Reserve]] and the [[European Central Bank]] for example) have been given independency and inflation control as their main objective.


Not withstanding its limitations as a policy instrument, the model remains the most common macroeconomic model taught to undergraduate students because of its pedagogical qualities.


==References==
==References==
<references/>
{{reflist}}

Latest revision as of 19:43, 7 March 2024

This article is developing and not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
Addendum [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.
There is a mathematical supplement to this article on the tutorials subpage.

The IS-LM model is used in the teaching of macroeconomics to depict the interaction of the factors determining the level of demand in an economy.

The Model

The two markets

The IS-LM model conceptualises the economy as consisting of two market in one of which occurs all of the purchases of goods and services that happen throughout the country and in the other of which occurs all of the purchases of financial assets. It shows how a country's national income may be jointly determined by the way people behave in the market for goods and services and the way they behave in the market for financial assets. In the market for goods, investment is taken to be the active element, with consumption being determined passively as what remains of national income after deducting what is assumed to be the more-or-less fixed proportion that goes into saving. The financial assets market is taken to be made up on the one hand of money, which is non-interest-bearing, and on the other of all of those assets (such as stocks, bonds and savings certificates) which, in one way or another, can be considered to be interest-bearing. The cost of holding money rather than interest-bearing assets is taken to be the interest payments that are thereby foregone, but people are taken to wish to hold a certain amount of money for day-to-day transactions.

ISLM.png

Model structure

In its graphical form the model is shown as a pair of intersecting curves relating the level of national income (on the horizontal axis) to the rate of interest (on the vertical axis).

  • The I-S (investment-savings) curve depicts those combinations of interest rate and income that are consistent with the equality of investment and saving.
  • The L-M (liquidity-money supply) curve shows, those combinations of interest rate and income that make the public just willing to hold a given quantity of money.

The shape of the I-S curve follows from the fact that a rise in interest rates tends to encourage saving and discourage investment, combined with the assumption that the amount that people save rises and falls with income in an unchanging relationship (termed the "propensity to save"). Then for saving to be kept in line with investment, a rise in the interest rate must be accompanied by fall in income so that the resulting fall in investment is accompanied by the balancing fall in saving. Conversely, a fall in the interest rate would be associated with an increase in income. So the I-S curve has to fall from left to right.

The shape of the L-M curve reflects two assumptions, one being the assumption that the quantity of money that the public wishes to hold in order to have it available for speculation falls as the interest rate rises, and the other being the assumption that the amount of money that is tied up in day-to-day transactions rises with a rise in national income. It follows from those assumptions that, at a given level of the total money supply, the process of reconciling the transactions demand with the speculative demand implies a positive association between national income and the rate of interest. So the L-M curve has to rise from left to right.

The way in which the model explains the tendency for the economy to settle down to an equilibrium following a shock or a sudden change in behaviour, can be examined in words by supposing that there is a reduction in the public's propensity to save, meaning that people spend more of their money on "consumption goods". That would prompt an increase in the supply of those goods, in the total income of those employed in their production, and thus an increase in national income. However, that increase in expenditure and income would mean that more of the available money would be used as "transactions balances" reducing the amount available for people to hold as cash reserves for speculative purposes. That would make people willing to pay more in interest to restore their speculative reserves and the resulting rise in interest rates would stimulate saving and discourage investment and so check the growth in income. The implied assumption is that those adjustments take place instantaneously and without regard for expected developments.

Interpretation

The model is widely used in the teaching of economics to discuss the relative effectiveness of fiscal policy and monetary policy as means of stabilising the economy.

The effect of using fiscal policy in the form of an increase in public expenditure, as represented as the effect of a shift to the right of the I-S curve, is to produce an additional rise of national income, the magnitude of which depends upon the slope of the L-M curve at the point of intersection - the steeper it is, the smaller will be the additional increase in national income. The steepness of the L-M curve depends, in turn on two factors:

  • the income elasticity of the demand for money, (meaning the extent to which the demand for money for to finance transactions increases in response to a change in national income). The higher is the income elasticity, the greater will be the interest rate increase need to bring the supply of money into equality with its supply and so the steeper will be the L-M curve.
  • the interest elasticity of demand for money (meaning the extent to which the demand for money falls in response to an increase in interest rates).

The higher is the interest elasticity, the flatter will be the L-M curve.

The effect of using monetary policy by increasing the money supply, as represented by a move to the right of the L-M curve, is to increase national income to an extent that depends upon the slope of the I-S curve at the point of intersection - the steeper is the I-S curve, the smaller will be the increase in national income. The slope of the I-S curve depends in turn upon:-

  • the interest elasticity of investment (meaning the response of investment to a change of interest rates). The higher is that elasticity, the larger will be the increase in national income in response to a fall in interest rate so the flatter will be the I-S curve.

The history of the model

The model was first put forward in a 1937 lecture by Sir John Hicks, who presented it then as a way of illustrating the relationship between the Keynesian theory of macroeconomics and the previously orthodox "classical theory" [1].

An important extension of the IS-LM model was built by Robert Mundell (1963) and Marcus Fleming (1962) in the 1960's. The Mundell-Fleming model describes a small open economy with one more curve representing equilibriums of international exchanges.

The limitations of the model

During the 1950’s and 1960’s microeconomic investigations on consumption and investment gave a better understanding of the IS slope. Milton Friedman developed the idea that the consumption level of household’s was mainly determined by a long-term expectation a theory known as the permanent income hypothesis[2]. Franco Modigliani life-cycle theory demonstrated that consumption was also related to age. Those two theories denied short-term policies to have an important effect on consumption, and thus the effects of the spending multiplier.

Such criticisms of Keynesian ideas were not always criticisms of the IS/LM model. In fact, economists like Milton Friedman used the IS/LM framework to confute Keynesian economics[3]. Yet Friedman rejected the paradigm of "general equilibrium" he viewed as characterized by "abstractness, generality, and mathematical elegance"[4]

The most severe criticisms of the IS/LM model came from the fact that it neglects private agents' expectations. Modern macroeconomic models which take expectations into accounts can provide results opposite to those of IS/LM. In fact, the model considers that short run is independent from long run. Yet expectations about the future have for example a direct impact on current wages which stimulates inflation and thus cancelled the positive effects of many macroeconomic policies described by the IS/LM model. In such cases, inflation remains the only effect and disturbs the coordination of private agents. The consequence of the rational expectations theory is that central banks of several industrial countries (the Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank for example) have been given independency and inflation control as their main objective.

Not withstanding its limitations as a policy instrument, the model remains the most common macroeconomic model taught to undergraduate students because of its pedagogical qualities.

References

  1. Hicks, J. R. (1937), "Mr. Keynes and the Classics - A Suggested Interpretation", Econometrica[1]
  2. Friedman, Milton (1957). A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton Univ Press.
  3. Bordo, Michael D. & Schwartz, Anna J. (2003), "IS-LM and Monetarism", National Bureau of Economic Research, p.18 [2]
  4. Milton Friedman (1949 (1953)), , "The Marshallian Demand Curve" in Essays in Positive Economics, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, pp. 47-99.