Economic efficiency: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 15: Line 15:
That way of adapting of the Pareto criterion  is known as ''compensation principle'', and it is strictly valid only if the compensation is actually paid.  
That way of adapting of the Pareto criterion  is known as ''compensation principle'', and it is strictly valid only if the compensation is actually paid.  


The practical application of the following definitions of the components of economic efficiency  may require the imputation of value judgments in order to give meaning to the concepts of social utility and social product which they employ.
The practical application of the following definitions of the components of economic efficiency  may require the imputation of value judgments in order to give meaning to the concepts of social utility and social product which they employ (other limitations are discussed in the article on [[Welfare economics]]).


===Productive efficiency===
===Productive efficiency===
Productive efficiency can be defined as the ratio of the quantity of  output of a product to the quantity of resources used to produce it.  Where the same resources can be used to produce more than one product, their optimum product  combinations form a ''production possibilities frontier'' (see the diagram on the tutorials subpage).  A loss of productive efficiency is definitionally the result of any  change that results in a non-optimal product combination.  The productive efficiency of an economy  can be increased  by an expansion of the production possibilities frontier as a result of  scale economies or  of an increase in the availability or the productivity of the factors of production.
Productive efficiency can be defined as the ratio of the quantity of  output of a product to the quantity of resources used to produce it.  Where the same resources can be used to produce more than one product, their optimum product  combinations form a ''production possibilities frontier'' (see the diagram on the tutorials subpage).  A loss of productive efficiency is definitionaly the result of any  change that results in a non-optimal product combination.  The productive efficiency of an economy  can be increased  by an expansion of the production possibilities frontier as a result of  scale economies or  of an increase in the availability or the productivity of the factors of production.


=== Allocative efficiency===
=== Allocative efficiency===
An economy achieves optimum allocative efficiency when it produces that combination of products which makes for the greatest consumer satisfaction – so that consumers would not wish to spend their money in any other wayAn increase in allocative efficiency using the Kaldor/Hicks criterion would occur if welfare gains from a change in the combination of goods produced would outweigh any resulting losses.
An economy achieves a definitionaly optimum allocation of resources between outputs  when it produces that combination which makes for the greatest social utility. Stated more precisely, resources
are allocated optimally between two products when the ratios of their marginal social utilities to their marginal social costs are equal - because  social utility could otherwise be increased by switching resources from one output to the other. The usefulness of this definition may be  limited, however, because unknown differences in the preferences for different outputs among individual consumers may  make their marginal social utilities hard to assess.  


===Distributional  efficiency===
===Distributional  efficiency===

Revision as of 08:27, 11 April 2008

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Efficiency is normally defined as a ratio of the quantity of some measure of output to the quantity of input required to bring it about. In economic theory, the desired output of economic activity is taken to be an increase in social utility, and the input required is some combination of the productive resources of land, labour and capital. The concept of efficiency is a product of the theory of welfare economics and is subject to the limitations noted in the article on that topic.


Definitions of efficiency

In principle the economic efficiency of an action is taken refer to the ratio of the increase in social utility that it produces to the aggregate quantity of the community's resources that it requires. In practice however, social utility cannot be defined without imputing value judgments concerning the distribution of income among individuals. The "Pareto criterion" evades that difficulty by the proposition that:

- an action is Pareto efficient only if it makes somebody better off without making anybody worse off.

Since most actions also make some people worse off, the Pareto criterion is too restrictive to be generally useful, and it is often replaced by the Kaldor-Hicks criterion, which requires that:

- an action is Kaldor-Hicks efficient only if it benefits those who gain from it after they have compensated those who lose from it.

That way of adapting of the Pareto criterion is known as compensation principle, and it is strictly valid only if the compensation is actually paid.

The practical application of the following definitions of the components of economic efficiency may require the imputation of value judgments in order to give meaning to the concepts of social utility and social product which they employ (other limitations are discussed in the article on Welfare economics).

Productive efficiency

Productive efficiency can be defined as the ratio of the quantity of output of a product to the quantity of resources used to produce it. Where the same resources can be used to produce more than one product, their optimum product combinations form a production possibilities frontier (see the diagram on the tutorials subpage). A loss of productive efficiency is definitionaly the result of any change that results in a non-optimal product combination. The productive efficiency of an economy can be increased by an expansion of the production possibilities frontier as a result of scale economies or of an increase in the availability or the productivity of the factors of production.

Allocative efficiency

An economy achieves a definitionaly optimum allocation of resources between outputs when it produces that combination which makes for the greatest social utility. Stated more precisely, resources are allocated optimally between two products when the ratios of their marginal social utilities to their marginal social costs are equal - because social utility could otherwise be increased by switching resources from one output to the other. The usefulness of this definition may be limited, however, because unknown differences in the preferences for different outputs among individual consumers may make their marginal social utilities hard to assess.

Distributional efficiency

Distributional efficiency is increased if the way that consumption is shared among households is changed in such a way as to increase aggregate welfare.

Limitations and applications

Limitations

The above definitions and classifications provide one of a number of conceptually possible frameworks for analysing economic activity, but they do not contribute directly to its understanding. Their contribution depends indirectly upon the uses to which they can be put, and those uses are subject to several limitations. Foremost is the fact that, because the welfare referred to is the welfare of the individuals affected as each of them perceives it, it cannot be aggregated. Secondly, the possibility of interactions within an economic system means that an improvement in one category of efficiency may not be reflected as an improvement in their combination. (For example, the merger of two large firms could lead both to a loss of allocative efficiency because of their gain in market power, and to a gain in productive efficiency because of scale economies. Similarly an increase in income support could lead both to an increase in distributional efficiency because of the diminishing marginal utility of wealth, and to a loss of productive efficiency because of the resulting change in recipients' relative preferences for work and leisure.) Thirdly, practical considerations often limit the possibility balancing of gains to one category of efficiency against the losses to another to cases where the balance is judgementally obvious. That difficulty can be so acute where distributional efficiency is involved, that refuge has to be taken in the presumption that distributional welfare gains and losses are a matter that can be put aside to be dealt with , if necessary, by redistributive taxes and benefits.

Applications

Despite those limitations, the concept of efficiency underlies much of the work of practising economists. The practice of cost/benefit analysis embodies the assumption that the welfare of an individual is increased by the free exchange of a particular good for claims upon alternative goods (ie money) - and that the benefit thereby gained is measurable by the price that he is willing to pay for it. By extension, that implies that an economy's allocative efficiency is increased if the total benefits so defined exceed the cost of provision of the good. The existing states of productive and distributive efficiency are normally assumed to be unaffected . The operation of competition policy depends upon the presumption that a reduction in a company’s market power or the removal of a barrier to competition will result in an increase in allocative efficiency (a presumption and its rebuttal according to the theory of the second best are explained in the article on competition). The adoption of a per se prohibition (based upon the form of a business practice) ignores the possibility of a consequent reduction in productive efficiency whereas an effects-based rule of reason prohibition can take account of that possibility.