Alfred Marshall: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Richard Jensen
(drop doubtful items)
m (Text replacement - "History of modern economic thought" to "History of economic thought")
 
(3 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
'''Alfred Marshall''' (1842-1924) was the most [[History of modern economic thought|influential economic theorist]] in the English speaking world in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, and his approach to [[microeconomics]] remains influential.
{{subpages}}
'''Alfred Marshall''' (1842-1924) was the most [[History of economic thought|influential economic theorist]] in the English speaking world in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, and his approach to [[microeconomics]] remains influential.


[[Image:Marshall.jpg|thumb|250px|Marshall in 1921]]
[[Image:Marshall.jpg|thumb|250px|Marshall in 1921]]
==Career==
==Career==
Marshall was born in Clapham, England, July 26, 1842. His father was a bank cashier and a devout Evangelical.  He studied mathematics at St. John's College, Cambridge University and quietly became an agnostic.  Marshall experienced a mental crisis that led him to abandon physics and switch to philosophy. He began with metaphysics, specifically "the philosophical foundation of knowledge, especially in relation to theology."<ref>Keynes, 1924</ref>. Metaphysics led Marshall to ethics, specifically a [[Henry Sigwick|Sidgwickian]] version of utilitarianism; ethics, in turn, led him to economics, because economics played an essential role in providing the preconditions for the improvement of the working class. Even as he turned to economics, his ethical views continued to be a dominant force in his thinking.   
Marshall was born in Clapham, England, July 26, 1842. His father was a bank cashier and a devout Evangelical.  He studied mathematics at St. John's College, Cambridge University and quietly became an agnostic.  Marshall experienced a mental crisis that led him to abandon physics and switch to philosophy. He began with metaphysics, specifically "the philosophical foundation of knowledge, especially in relation to theology."<ref>Keynes, 1924</ref>. Metaphysics led Marshall to ethics, specifically a [[Henry Sidgwick|Sidgwickian]] version of utilitarianism; ethics, in turn, led him to economics, because economics played an essential role in providing the preconditions for the improvement of the working class. Even as he turned to economics, his ethical views continued to be a dominant force in his thinking.   


In 1885 he became professor of political economy at Cambridge, where he remained until his retirement in 1908.  Over the years he interacted with many British thinkers including [[Henry Sidgwick]], W.K. Clifford, Benjamin Jowett, [[William Stanley Jevons]], Francis Ysidro Edgworth, John Neville Keynes and [[John Maynard Keynes]].  Marshall founded the "Cambridge School" which paid special attention to increasing returns, the theory of the firm, and welfare economics; after his retirement leadership passed to [[Alfred Pigou]] and [[John Maynard Keynes]].
In 1885 he became professor of political economy at Cambridge, where he remained until his retirement in 1908.  Over the years he interacted with many British thinkers including [[Henry Sidgwick]], W.K. Clifford, Benjamin Jowett, [[William Stanley Jevons]], Francis Ysidro Edgworth, John Neville Keynes and [[John Maynard Keynes]].  Marshall founded the "Cambridge School" which paid special attention to increasing returns, the theory of the firm, and welfare economics; after his retirement leadership passed to [[Alfred Pigou]] and [[John Maynard Keynes]].


==Principles of Economics==
==Principles of Economics==
Marshall's chief work, ''Principles of Economics'' (1890)  established his reputation. It appeared in 8 editions and greatly great influenced the teaching of economics in English-speaking countries. In it he sought to reconcile the classical and modern theories of value. [[John Stuart Mill]] had examined the relationship between the value of commodities and their production costs, on the theory that value depends on effort expended in manufacture. [[W. S. Jevons]] and the [[Marginal Utility]] theorists had elaborated a theory of value based on the idea of maximizing utility, holding that value depends on demand. Marshall's work used both these approaches, but he particularly examined the factor of costs. He pointed out that, in the short run, supply cannot be changed and market value depends mainly on demand. In a period of intermediate length, production can be aided by existing facilities, such as buildings and machinery; but since these do not require renewal within this intermediate period their costs, which commonly are called fixed, overhead, or supplementary costs, have little influence on the sale price of the product. Marshall pointed out that it is the prime or variable costs, which constantly recur, that influence the sale price most in this period. In a still longer period, machines and buildings wear out and have to be replaced, so that the sale price of the product must be high enough to cover such replacement costs. This classification of costs into fixed and variable and the emphasis given to the element of time probably represent Marshall's chief contributions to economic theory.  He was committed to partial equilibrium models over general equilibrium on the grounds that the inherently dynamical nature of economics made the former more practically useful.
Marshall's chief work, ''Principles of Economics'' (1890)  established his reputation. It appeared in 8 editions, starting at 750 pages and growing to 870 pages. It decisively shaped the teaching of economics in English-speaking countries. Its main technical contribution was a masterful analysis of the issues of elasticity, consumer surplus, increasing and diminishing returns, short and long terms, and marginal utility; many of the ideas were original with Marshall, others were improved version of ideas by [[W. S. Jevons]] and others. 
 
In a broader sense Marshall hoped to reconcile the classical and modern theories of value. [[John Stuart Mill]] had examined the relationship between the value of commodities and their production costs, on the theory that value depends on effort expended in manufacture. Jevons and the [[Marginal Utility]] theorists had elaborated a theory of value based on the idea of maximizing utility, holding that value depends on demand. Marshall's work used both these approaches, but he particularly examined the factor of costs. He pointed out that, in the short run, supply cannot be changed and market value depends mainly on demand. In a period of intermediate length, production can be aided by existing facilities, such as buildings and machinery; but since these do not require renewal within this intermediate period their costs, which commonly are called fixed, overhead, or supplementary costs, have little influence on the sale price of the product. Marshall pointed out that it is the prime or variable costs, which constantly recur, that influence the sale price most in this period. In a still longer period, machines and buildings wear out and have to be replaced, so that the sale price of the product must be high enough to cover such replacement costs. This classification of costs into fixed and variable and the emphasis given to the element of time probably represent Marshall's chief contributions to economic theory.  He was committed to partial equilibrium models over general equilibrium on the grounds that the inherently dynamical nature of economics made the former more practically useful.  A second volume was planned but never written; it was to cover foreign trade, money, trade fluctuations, taxation, collectivism, and social goals.


Much of the success of Marshall's teaching and ''Principles'' book derived from his effective use of diagrams, which were soon emulated by other teachers worldwide.<ref> Cook (2005)</ref>
Much of the success of Marshall's teaching and ''Principles'' book derived from his effective use of diagrams, which were soon emulated by other teachers worldwide.<ref> Cook (2005)</ref>
==Monetary theory==
==Monetary theory==
Marshall made important contributions through his exposition of the quantity theory of money and his distinction between the "real" rate of interest and the "money" rate. His views on currency, as expressed before government commissions in 1887 and 1899, are given in ''Official Papers by Alfred Marshall'' (1926).  
Marshall made important contributions through his exposition of the quantity theory of money and his distinction between the "real" rate of interest and the "money" rate. He was often called upon to give expert opinion to government commissions on all sorts of topics; some statements appeared posthumously in ''Official Papers by Alfred Marshall'' (1926). In 1890 he helped found the British Economic Association (later the Royal Economic Society) and the ''Economic Journal'', the leading economics journal in Britain.


Marshall took a broad approach to social science in which economics plays an important but limited role. He recognized that in the real world, economic life is tightly bound up with ethical, social and political currents--currents he felt economists should not ignore.  Marshall envisioned dramatic social change involving the elimination of poverty and a sharp reduction of inequality. He saw the duty of economics was to improve material conditions, but such improvement would occur, Marshall believed, only in connection with social and political forces. His interest in liberalism, socialism, trade unions, women's education, poverty and progress reflect the influence of his early social philosophy to his later activities and writings.
Marshall took a broad approach to social science in which economics plays an important but limited role. He recognized that in the real world, economic life is tightly bound up with ethical, social and political currents--currents he felt economists should not ignore.  Marshall envisioned dramatic social change involving the elimination of poverty and a sharp reduction of inequality. He saw the duty of economics was to improve material conditions, but such improvement would occur, Marshall believed, only in connection with social and political forces. His interest in liberalism, socialism, trade unions, women's education, poverty and progress reflect the influence of his early social philosophy to his later activities and writings.


 
==References==
==Bibliography==
<references/>
* Backhouse, Roger E. "Sidgwick, Marshall, and the Cambridge School of Economics." ''History of Political Economy'' 2006 38(1): 15-44. Issn: 0018-2702 Fulltext: [[Ebsco]]
* Groenewegen, Peter. ''A Soaring Eagle: Alfred Marshall: 1842-1924'' (1995) 880pp, the major scholarly biography
* Keynes, John Maynard. "Alfred Marshall, 1842-1924," ''The Economic Journal'' 34#135 September, 1924 pp. 311-372 [http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28192409%2934%3A135%3C311%3AAM1%3E2.0.CO%3B2-H in JSTOR]
* Raffaelli, Tiziano et al. ''The Elgar Companion to Alfred Marshall'' 2006. 752 ISBN: 1-84376-072-X.
* Cook, Simon. "Late Victorian Visual Reasoning and Alfred Marshall's Economic Science." ''British Journal for the History of Science'' 2005 38(2): 179-195. Issn: 0007-0874
 
 
 
* DNB article
 
==Works by Marshall==
* ''The Economics of Industry'' (1879), in collaboration with his wife Maty Paley Marshall [http://books.google.com/books?id=wFc4yr9xfqAC&dq=inauthor:alfred+inauthor:marshall&num=30&as_brr=1  online edition]
* ''Principles of Economics'' (1890)  [http://books.google.com/books?id=yK4JAAAAIAAJ&dq=inauthor:alfred+inauthor:marshall&num=30&as_brr=1 online edition]
* ''Industry and Trade'' (1919)
* ''Money, Credit, and Commerce'' (1923)
* ''Official Papers by Alfred Marshall'' (1926).
 
==See also==
* [[History of modern economic thought]]
* [[Microeconomics]]

Latest revision as of 23:11, 7 March 2024

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Works [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Alfred Marshall (1842-1924) was the most influential economic theorist in the English speaking world in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, and his approach to microeconomics remains influential.

Marshall in 1921

Career

Marshall was born in Clapham, England, July 26, 1842. His father was a bank cashier and a devout Evangelical. He studied mathematics at St. John's College, Cambridge University and quietly became an agnostic. Marshall experienced a mental crisis that led him to abandon physics and switch to philosophy. He began with metaphysics, specifically "the philosophical foundation of knowledge, especially in relation to theology."[1]. Metaphysics led Marshall to ethics, specifically a Sidgwickian version of utilitarianism; ethics, in turn, led him to economics, because economics played an essential role in providing the preconditions for the improvement of the working class. Even as he turned to economics, his ethical views continued to be a dominant force in his thinking.

In 1885 he became professor of political economy at Cambridge, where he remained until his retirement in 1908. Over the years he interacted with many British thinkers including Henry Sidgwick, W.K. Clifford, Benjamin Jowett, William Stanley Jevons, Francis Ysidro Edgworth, John Neville Keynes and John Maynard Keynes. Marshall founded the "Cambridge School" which paid special attention to increasing returns, the theory of the firm, and welfare economics; after his retirement leadership passed to Alfred Pigou and John Maynard Keynes.

Principles of Economics

Marshall's chief work, Principles of Economics (1890) established his reputation. It appeared in 8 editions, starting at 750 pages and growing to 870 pages. It decisively shaped the teaching of economics in English-speaking countries. Its main technical contribution was a masterful analysis of the issues of elasticity, consumer surplus, increasing and diminishing returns, short and long terms, and marginal utility; many of the ideas were original with Marshall, others were improved version of ideas by W. S. Jevons and others.

In a broader sense Marshall hoped to reconcile the classical and modern theories of value. John Stuart Mill had examined the relationship between the value of commodities and their production costs, on the theory that value depends on effort expended in manufacture. Jevons and the Marginal Utility theorists had elaborated a theory of value based on the idea of maximizing utility, holding that value depends on demand. Marshall's work used both these approaches, but he particularly examined the factor of costs. He pointed out that, in the short run, supply cannot be changed and market value depends mainly on demand. In a period of intermediate length, production can be aided by existing facilities, such as buildings and machinery; but since these do not require renewal within this intermediate period their costs, which commonly are called fixed, overhead, or supplementary costs, have little influence on the sale price of the product. Marshall pointed out that it is the prime or variable costs, which constantly recur, that influence the sale price most in this period. In a still longer period, machines and buildings wear out and have to be replaced, so that the sale price of the product must be high enough to cover such replacement costs. This classification of costs into fixed and variable and the emphasis given to the element of time probably represent Marshall's chief contributions to economic theory. He was committed to partial equilibrium models over general equilibrium on the grounds that the inherently dynamical nature of economics made the former more practically useful. A second volume was planned but never written; it was to cover foreign trade, money, trade fluctuations, taxation, collectivism, and social goals.

Much of the success of Marshall's teaching and Principles book derived from his effective use of diagrams, which were soon emulated by other teachers worldwide.[2]

Monetary theory

Marshall made important contributions through his exposition of the quantity theory of money and his distinction between the "real" rate of interest and the "money" rate. He was often called upon to give expert opinion to government commissions on all sorts of topics; some statements appeared posthumously in Official Papers by Alfred Marshall (1926). In 1890 he helped found the British Economic Association (later the Royal Economic Society) and the Economic Journal, the leading economics journal in Britain.

Marshall took a broad approach to social science in which economics plays an important but limited role. He recognized that in the real world, economic life is tightly bound up with ethical, social and political currents--currents he felt economists should not ignore. Marshall envisioned dramatic social change involving the elimination of poverty and a sharp reduction of inequality. He saw the duty of economics was to improve material conditions, but such improvement would occur, Marshall believed, only in connection with social and political forces. His interest in liberalism, socialism, trade unions, women's education, poverty and progress reflect the influence of his early social philosophy to his later activities and writings.

References

  1. Keynes, 1924
  2. Cook (2005)