Law of diminishing returns

From Citizendium
Revision as of 06:06, 31 January 2012 by imported>Nick Gardner (→‎The classical concept)
Jump to navigation Jump to search
This article is developing and not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.

The law of diminishing returns is an abstract concept in economic theory. It states that the output per input (productivity) declines if the input of a production factor is increased over a certain limit. It has two versions, one of which is a tautology and the other of which lacks empirical support.

The classical concept

(CC) Image: Paul Schächterle
Production function (blue) with first rising and then diminishing marginal (green) and average (magenta) returns.

In classical economics the law states that the highest productivity is gained when there is an optimal proportion between the factors of production. Any divergence from that proportion will result in lower productivity. It is a tautology being no more than than a restatement of the definition of the term "optimum".

If one production factor is fixed, the proportion between the production factors will change with rising production i.e. rising input of the variable factor. According to the classical LDR this leads to a production function that has four phases with the following characteristics:

  1. Rising marginal productivity, rising average productivity.
  2. Diminishing marginal productivity, rising average productivity.
  3. Diminishing average productivity.

History

Historically the concept was first developed by Anne Robert Jacques Turgot. It was mainly related to agricultural production and the use of labour and later fertilizer in relation to a fixed amount of soil.[1]

The neoclassical concept

(CC) Image: Paul Schächterle
Production function (blue) with decreasing returns to scale (green) and therefore decreasing average returns (magenta).

In neoclassical economics the LDR signifies that an increasing input of any production factor will result in diminishing marginal productivity. This leads to a production function with the following characteristics:

  • Zero input of a production factor results in zero output i.e. the graph starts at the origin.
  • Marginal productivity is highest with the lowest possible input, i.e. the point closest to an input of zero.
  • Marginal productivity decreases continuously.

History

The origins of the neoclassical production function i.e. the neoclassical LDR date back to the time of classical economics. Then the concept was used to describe the effect of an increase in wheat production where good soils were limited. To increase the production of wheat inferior soils would have to be used, which would deliver less wheat for the same amount of labour.[2]

Neoclassical economists extended the idea to the claim that any economically rational producer would use any production factor first for the most productive task, then for the next productive task, etc., and/or would use the best unit first, then the second best, etc. Thus the idea got applied to all production factors.

Implications

The general validity of the neoclassical LDR is a necessary condition for the existence of a stable equilibrium in the General Equilibrium Theory (production sets must be convex).

Critique

The argumentation on which the neoclassical LDR is based assumes that there are units of a factor with different quality and/or there are fields of application of the factor with different productivity.[3]

Combining both concepts

(CC) Image: Paul Schächterle
Cobb-Douglas production function with 2 factors and production elasticity complying to the neoclassical LDR, i.e. overall decreasing returns to scale.

Neoclassical theory usually distinguishes between only two factors of production: capital and labour. With just two factors of production the production function can be represented by a 3-dimensional graph.

Tho most prominent production function for creating such a graph is the Cobb-Douglas production function: Y = A × Ca × Lb, where Y stands for yield, C for capital, L for labour, and A, a and b are constants that can be interpreted as A for technology level and a and b for the production elasticities of the factors. This formula can contain elements of both concepts, the classical and the neoclassical LDR.

The classical concept is represented by the fact that a combination of both factors results in a square output so that an even proportion between the factors results in higher productivity.

The neoclassical concept is represented by the fact that each factor has diminishing returns to scale as long as (a < 1) and (b < 1). Note that the combined input of both factors only results in diminishing returns as long as (a + b < 1). If both factors independently have decreasing returns to scale (a < 1, b < 1), their combination might still lead to increasing returns to scale (a + b > 1).

For an interactive demonstration of the Cobb-Douglas production function see: [1]

Naming conventions

Viewing their attributed originators the names for both concepts may seem misleading. Turgot is considered physiocrat, not classical economist, and Ricardo is considered classical, not neoclassical economist. Yet the names of both concepts reflect the eras of their further development and refinement.

References

  1. Turgot, Observations sur le mémoire de M. de Saint-Péravy en faveur de l’impôt indirect, 1768. In: Turgot, Anne Robert Jacques (1727—1781), Oeuvres de Turgot, 1966, pp. 418 sqq., (421), Gallica, Bibliothèque nationale de France
  2. David Ricardo, 1772—1823, An Essay on Profits, 1815
  3. Felderer/Homburg, Makroökonomik und neue Makroökonomik, S. 55, Fn. 4