Market (economics)

From Citizendium
Revision as of 09:36, 26 October 2010 by imported>Nick Gardner (→‎Market characteristics)
Jump to navigation Jump to search
This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

The uses of the term

The word "market" is commonly used to distinguish transactions between individuals from other ways of allocating goods and services. The term "market economy", for example, is often used to describe a society in which most business decisions are made by individuals and companies, rather than by the government - which, as a political regime, is generally known as "capitalism". It is also used as a noun to refer to an institution that facilitates such transactions, and as a verb to denote the activity of promoting them. In many contexts it is used as a way of making general statements that characterise a range of different arrangements.

Markets in the real world

Market characteristics

The concept of "market structure" concerns the proportion of the items that are supplied that comes from a few suppliers, or the proportion of items acquired that go to a few purchasers. Its practical importance derives from its association with "market power", which is the ability to influence the prices at which items change hands. (The policy implications of market power are discussed below in the paragraph headed competition policy.) Measures of market structure include the 5-firm concentration ratio and the Herfindahl Index. Suppliers can increase their market power by mergers, restrictive trade practices or innovation.

The speed with which a market price responds to a sudden change in the supply of, or demand for, its product is termed its price flexibility. Price flexibility may be limited by search friction or by commercial or regulatory market constraints.

Markets do not, by definition, exist for public goods (such as open spaces and lighthouses) that are not paid for by individual users because of the difficulty of restricting access or use. Where those difficulties can be overcome at a cost (as in road pricing), the cost of ovecoming them is a relevant market characteristic.

The principal markets

Product markets

Labour markets

Commodity markets

Financial markets

Markets in economic theory

The basic concept

In economic theory, a market exists when a would-be buyer makes contact with a would-be seller for the purpose of agreeing an exchange. In his Principles of Economics Alfred Marshall offered several definitions and gave a range of examples [1].

The Walrasian auctioneer

Market friction

"The market for lemons"

Perfect markets

Marshall also introduced the concept of a perfect market when he wrote .. the more nearly perfect a market is, the stronger is the tendency for the same price to be paid for the same thing at the same time in all parts of the market. The hypothetical ideal of a perfect market has since been developed to mean a situation in which:

  • price is determined by the costless interaction of collective supply with collective demand;
  • all information that is relevant to the price of a commodity is immediately known to all market participants;
  • all market participants act rationally;
  • it is impossible for any individual participants or groups of participants to influence the price of a product.

The efficient market hypothesis

Adaptive markets

Policy implications

Responses to market failure

Public goods

Competition policy

Financial regulation

References