Market (economics): Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
No edit summary
Line 25: Line 25:


The traditional way of organising a secondary market involved a physical location (termed an "exchange" or a "pit"),  at which dealers matched [[ask price]]s with [[bid price]]s by "open outcry". That organisational form has now been replaced almost everywhere by the use of telephonic or electronic communication.  The term "electronic market" has come to denote the use of computer software to make bargains automatically by electronically matching ask prices and bid prices. [[Settlement (finance)|Settlement]], involving the transfer of payments and purchases, takes place after the completion of bargains, and is usually the work of [[clearing house]]s.
The traditional way of organising a secondary market involved a physical location (termed an "exchange" or a "pit"),  at which dealers matched [[ask price]]s with [[bid price]]s by "open outcry". That organisational form has now been replaced almost everywhere by the use of telephonic or electronic communication.  The term "electronic market" has come to denote the use of computer software to make bargains automatically by electronically matching ask prices and bid prices. [[Settlement (finance)|Settlement]], involving the transfer of payments and purchases, takes place after the completion of bargains, and is usually the work of [[clearing house]]s.
<!--
The use of secondary markets is necessarily confined to items whose quality is closely defined by generally accepted standards, such as [[security|securities]], currencies, and certain commodities. Where generally accepted definitions are not available - as in many primary markets - the judgement of quality becomes part of the bargaining process, and the degree of [[asymmetric information|information asymmetry]] between buyers and sellers. 
-->


 
==Commercial markets==
 
<ref>[http://www.medieval-life-and-times.info/medieval-life/medieval-fairs.htm ''Medieval Fairs'', Medieval Life and Times]</ref>
<ref>[http://www.history.ac.uk/cmh/gaz/gazweb2.html ''Gazeteer of Markets and Fairs in England and Wales to 1516]</ref>
 
==Some commercial markets==
===Product markets===
===Product markets===



Revision as of 16:21, 31 October 2010

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

The uses of the term

The word "market" is commonly used to distinguish transactions between individuals from other ways of allocating goods and services. The term "market economy", for example, is often used to describe a society in which most business decisions are made by individuals and companies, rather than by the government - which, as a political regime, is generally known as capitalism. It is also used as a noun to refer to an institution that facilitates such transactions, and as a verb to denote the activity of promoting them.

The term "the market", has a different usage, however. That usage refers to a theoretical model of a process by which prices are determined by supply and demand (a graphical representation of which can be seen in most economics textbooks). That model depends entirely upon deduction from untested axioms, and, without empirical support, it has limited application to the real world. Empirical evidence indicates that, in fact, market behaviour is strongly influenced by the characteristics of the institutions within which trading takes place.

Market characteristics

Markets can be categorised by their openness, structure, flexibility, stability, their degree of information assymetry, and the difficulty of restricting access.

The term openness is here used to denote freedom from regulations concerning, for example, prices quality and permission to trade.

The concept of market structure concerns the proportion of the items that are supplied that comes from a few suppliers, or the proportion of items acquired that go to a few purchasers. Its practical importance derives from its association with "market power", which is the ability to influence the prices at which items change hands. (The policy implications of market power are discussed below in the paragraph headed competition policy.) Measures of market structure include the 5-firm concentration ratio and the Herfindahl Index. Suppliers can increase their market power by mergers, restrictive trade practices or innovation.

The concept of market flexibility is conerned with the speed with which a market price responds to a sudden change in the supply of, or demand for, its product. Flexibility may be limited by search friction or by commercial or regulatory market constraints.

Markets also differ as to their stability. Instability can develop in markets that require the use of credit if circumstances, such as a demand shock, create a general fear of default. Fear of default can result in a reinforcing rise in the incidence of default - a continuing process that could lead to systemic market failure.

Information asymmetry occurs when the seller has information about the subject of a bargain that is not available to the buyer.

Markets do not, by definition, exist for public goods (such as open spaces and lighthouses) that are not paid for by individual users because of the difficulty of restricting access or use. Where those difficulties can be overcome at a cost (as in road pricing), the cost of overcoming them is a relevant market characteristic.

Market organisation

The term "primary market" refers to one of a variety of organisational arrangements in which buyers deal directly with sellers. All early markets were of that sort. A later development was the creation of "secondary markets" in which transactions are made between specialist "dealers", acting on behalf of prospective buyers and sellers. One way of organising a primary market is to bring together numbers of mutually independent sellers with numbers of mutually independent buyers, either by attending a physical market place, or by using a telephonic or electronic communications centre. Another is to arrange an "auction", in which competing bids for the purchase of goods are made by groups of mutually independent buyers. There are many different ways of organising auctions, and they, too, can involve either attendance or communication.

The traditional way of organising a secondary market involved a physical location (termed an "exchange" or a "pit"), at which dealers matched ask prices with bid prices by "open outcry". That organisational form has now been replaced almost everywhere by the use of telephonic or electronic communication. The term "electronic market" has come to denote the use of computer software to make bargains automatically by electronically matching ask prices and bid prices. Settlement, involving the transfer of payments and purchases, takes place after the completion of bargains, and is usually the work of clearing houses.

Commercial markets

Product markets

Labour markets

Commodity markets

Financial markets

The economics of the market

The basic concept

In economic theory, a market exists when a would-be buyer makes contact with a would-be seller for the purpose of agreeing an exchange. In his Principles of Economics Alfred Marshall offered several definitions and gave a range of examples [1].

The Walrasian auctioneer

Institutional influences

Market friction

"The market for lemons"

Perfect markets

Marshall also introduced the concept of a perfect market when he wrote .. the more nearly perfect a market is, the stronger is the tendency for the same price to be paid for the same thing at the same time in all parts of the market. The hypothetical ideal of a perfect market has since been developed to mean a situation in which:

  • price is determined by the costless interaction of collective supply with collective demand;
  • all information that is relevant to the price of a commodity is immediately known to all market participants;
  • all market participants act rationally;
  • it is impossible for any individual participants or groups of participants to influence the price of a product.

The efficient market hypothesis

Adaptive markets

Policy implications

Responses to market failure

Public goods

Competition policy

Financial regulation

References