Supply and demand: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
mNo edit summary
 
(41 intermediate revisions by 5 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{subpages}}
{{subpages}}
Because of their importance  to the development of economic theory, an appreciation of the concepts of '''supply and demand''' is essential to the understanding of economic theory. This article seeks to explain their significance in non-technical terms and to provide a simple introduction to the law of supply and demand, with links to more detailed explanations.


Because of their importance  to the development of economic theory, an appreciation  of  the significance of the  concepts of supply and demand is essential to the understanding of much of the subject-matter of economics. This article seeks to explain their significance in non-technical terms, as well as introducing the lay reader to some of the associated terminology used by economists and providing a simple introduction to the concepts for students of economics.  
Definitions of the terms used in the article that are shown in italics can be found on the Related Articles subpage, and a selection of the diagrams and mathematical equations that are conventionally used for teaching purposes can be found on the Tutorials subpage.


Definitions of the terms used in the article that are shown in italics can be found on the Related Articles subpage, and a selection of the diagrams and mathematical equations that are conventionally used for teaching purposes can be found on the Tutorials subpage
==Origins and applications==
The proposition that prices are determined by supply and demand is so familiar that it seems like a statement of the obvious. In fact,  it was not generally accepted, even by eminent intellectuals such as [[Adam Smith]], [[John Stuart Mill]] and [[David Ricardo]], until the idea was popularised by [[Alfred Marshall]] towards the end of the nineteenth century.<ref>[http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/ Alfred Marshall ''Principles of Economics'' Book V Macmillan 1964]</ref> <ref> For previous beliefs, see the article on [[history of economic thought]]</ref> Since then  there has been general acceptance of the proposition that demand rises in response to a reduction in price, that  supply rises in response to an increase in price, and that price somehow settles to a level where demand is  equal to supply.
That proposition has come to be been termed "the law of supply and demand" and  is often thought to be as firmly established as the law of gravity.  In fact it is what Marshall termed "a statement of a tendency", depending upon particular premises about human behaviour, and some economists have questioned its logical consistency <ref> For an account of some accusations  of inconsistency, see the tutorials subpage of this article</ref>. It has nevertheless survived in general use as a robust statement that reflects widespread experience. In economics, it has served as a tool that has been used in the construction of other theories,  and it has generated a terminology that has been widely used in discussions among economists.


==Overview: origins and applications==
==Demand==
The proposition that prices are determined by supply and demand is so familiar that it seems like a statement of the obvious. In fact,  it was not generally known, even to eminent intellectuals such as Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill and David Ricardo, until the idea was popularised by Alfred Marshal towards the end of the nineteenth century <ref>[http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP0.html Alfred Marshall ''Principles of Economics'' Book V Macmillan 1964]</ref>. <ref> For previous beliefs, see the article on [[history of economic thought]]</ref> Since then it has become universally accepted that demand rises in response to a reduction in price, that  supply rises in response to an increase in price, and that price somehow settles to a level where demand is  equal to supply.
That proposition has come to be been termed "the law of supply and demand" and  is often thought to be  as firmly established as the law of gravity.  In fact it is what Marshall termed "a statement of a tendency", depending upon particular premises about human behaviour, and falling  short of a complete explanation of the market mechanism. It has nevertheless survived in general use as a robust statement that reflects widespread experience. In economics,  it has served as a tool that has been used in the construction of other theories,  and it has generated a terminology that has been widely used in discussions among economists.


==Demand==
===Price effects===
===Price effects===
The basic premise that economists adopt when discussing demand was stated by Marshall as the proposition that "the larger the amount of a thing that a person has, the less ... will be the price which he will pay for a little more of it" -  a proposition that they referred to as the "law of diminishing ''marginal utility''". That premise has detailed  implications for the price/demand relationship that are discussed on the Tutorials subpage, but the only implication that is necessary to the operation of  the law of supply and demand is that demand rises in response to a reduction in price and vice versa.  Among exceptions to this generally-observed behaviour are goods that people prize just because they are expensive - sometimes referred to as ''Veblen goods'' in reference to the economist who coined the phrase "conspicuous consumption". An increase (or decrease) in the price charged for a product usually has two effects: - one is to cause consumers to switch their buying from (or to) it, to (or from) other products; and  the other is to bring about a reduction (or increase) in consumers' incomes with the consequences described in the following paragraph. Those two consequences of a price change are termed the ''substitution effect'' and the ''income effect''. (In this context "substitution" refers to a switch to or from any other product. The particular effects of  substitutes that serve as functional alternatives are described in a later paragraph).  From a supplier's viewpoint, however,  the relevant characteristic of the relationship between price and demand  is the percentage increase of demand for a product that would result from a small percentage reduction in its existing price - a quantity known as the ''price elasticity of demand'' for the product.
The basic premise that economists adopt when discussing demand was stated by Marshall as the proposition that "the larger the amount of a thing that a person has, the less ... will be the price which he will pay for a little more of it" -  a proposition that they referred to as the [[law of diminishing marginal utility|law of diminishing ''marginal utility'']]. That premise has detailed  implications for the price/demand relationship that are discussed on the Tutorials subpage, but the only implication that is necessary to the operation of  the law of supply and demand is that demand rises in response to a reduction in price and vice versa.   
 
Among exceptions to this generally-observed behaviour are goods that people prize just because they are expensive - sometimes referred to as [[Veblen good]]s in reference to the economist [[Thorstein Veblen]] who coined the phrase "[[conspicuous consumption]]".  
 
An increase (or decrease) in the price charged for a product usually has two effects: - one is to cause consumers to switch their buying from (or to) it, to (or from) other products; and  the other is to bring about a reduction (or increase) in consumers' incomes with the consequences described in the following paragraph. Those two consequences of a price change are termed the [[substitution effect]] and the [[income effect]]. (In this context "substitution" refers to a switch to or from any other product. The particular effects of  substitutes that serve as functional alternatives are described in a later paragraph).  From a supplier's viewpoint, however,  the relevant characteristic of the relationship between price and demand  is the percentage increase of demand for a product that would result from a small percentage reduction in its existing price - a quantity known as the ''price elasticity of demand'' for the product.


===Income effects===
===Income effects===
The missing passage in the above quotation from Marshall's Principles of Economics was his "other things being equal" qualification; and income is one of the other things that have to be taken into account. The effect of a rise in a community's  income must  obviously be a proportionately equal increase in its total spending, assuming no change in the  proportion  that it saves. That implies a community-wide ''income elasticity of demand '' of exactly one - but, within  that average,  different values pertain to different categories of product.  It is common experience for example, that people spend a diminishing proportion on food as their incomes rise (an observation that is sometimes referred to as "Engel's Law"). There are circumstances in which Engel's law can have significant consequences. In international trade, its effect is a continuing deterioration in the [[terms of trade]] of food-exporting countries with every rise in the prosperity of their customer countries; and in some developing countries the ''income effect'' referred to in the previous paragraph can produce an exception to the law of supply and demand that is similar to that of ''Veblen goods'', but for a different reason.  In markets predominated by people whose income is spent mainly on a basic good such as rice, the ''income effect'' of a reduction in its price can lead them to spend less upon it, thus reversing the normal effect of a price reduction. (Goods to which this exception  applies are termed ''Giffen goods''). Corresponding to Engel's law at the other end of the spectrum, the ''income elasticity of demand'' of luxury goods such as sports cars and jewelery is usually well above one.
The missing passage in the above quotation from Marshall's Principles of Economics was his "other things being equal" qualification; and income is one of the other things that have to be taken into account. The effect of a rise in a community's  income must  obviously be a proportionately equal increase in its total spending, assuming no change in the  proportion  that it saves. That implies a community-wide ''income elasticity of demand '' of exactly one - but, within  that average,  different values pertain to different categories of product.  It is common experience for example, that people spend a diminishing proportion on food as their incomes rise (an observation that is sometimes referred to as [[Engel's Law]]). There are circumstances in which Engel's law can have significant consequences. In international trade, its effect is a continuing deterioration in the [[terms of trade]] of food-exporting countries with every rise in the prosperity of their customer countries; and in some developing countries the ''income effect'' referred to in the previous paragraph can produce an exception to the law of supply and demand that is similar to that of ''Veblen goods'', but for a different reason.  In markets predominated by people whose income is spent mainly on a basic good such as rice, the ''income effect'' of a reduction in its price can lead them to spend less upon it, thus reversing the normal effect of a price reduction. (Goods to which this exception  applies are termed [[Giffen good]]s). Corresponding to Engel's law at the other end of the spectrum, the ''income elasticity of demand'' of luxury goods such as sports cars and jewelery is usually well above one.


=== Demand with substitutes and complements===
=== Demand with substitutes and complements===
The demand for a product is reduced if a new substitute becomes available - as happened to CDs when DVDs became available - and is increased if the price of an existing substitute is increased. The converse applies to complementary goods, so that the demand for microwave ovens  is increased  by the introduction of improved microwaveable meals,  and the demand for cars  is reduced  if the price of petrol is increased. The sensitivity of the demand for a product to a change in the price of a substitute or a  complement is referred to as the ''cross elasticity of demand'' between the products,  and is positive for substitutes and negative for complementary goods. However, in estimating the  net effect upon demand of any  price change, allowance has also to be taken of its effect upon consumers' incomes.
The demand for a product is reduced if a new substitute becomes available - as happened to CDs when DVDs became available - and is increased if the price of an existing substitute is increased. The converse applies to complementary goods, so that the demand for microwave ovens  is increased  by the introduction of improved microwaveable meals,  and the demand for cars  is reduced  if the price of petrol is increased. The sensitivity of the demand for a product to a change in the price of a substitute or a  complement is referred to as the [[cross elasticity of demand]] between the products,  and is positive for substitutes and negative for complementary goods. However, in estimating the  net effect upon demand of any  price change, allowance has also to be taken of its effect upon consumers' incomes.


==Supply==
==Supply==
===Diminishing returns===
===The [[production function]]===
The inferences of economic theory concerning the determination of supply relationships are less well established than those concerning demand, and they have been the subject of the controversy that is summarised on the tutorials subpage. The consensus view is that the premise that an increase in the price of a product results in an increase in its supply is justified by the ''law of diminishing returns''.
The price necessary to generate a particular supply of a product is taken to be that which is "just sufficient to induce capitalists to invest their capital, and workers of all grades to invest their personal capital" <ref>[http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP.html Alfred Marshall: ''Principles of Economics'', p497,  ]</ref>. For the price to increase with  increasing supply implies a [[production function]] for which every increase of output requires an increasing quantity of inputs -  conforming, that is to say, to the "law of diminishing returns". In the alternative case of constant returns, price is determined solely by the cost of production <ref>[http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/See Alfred Marshall ''Principles of Economics'' Book V Chapter III, Macmillan 1964]</ref>.
===Supply with substitutes and complements===
Supply is also affected by the prices of substitutes and complements in the markets for the inputs used in production. Where  nurses are used as substitutes for doctors, an increase in the pay of doctors would increase the demand for nurses, but where  doctors and nurses perform complementary functions, it would reduce the demand for nurses. However, the concept of cross-elasticity has less currency in this context than in connection with demand.


==Market interactions==
==Market interactions==
===The Auctioneer analogy===
===The Auctioneer analogy===
The original theory of supply and demand  offered no explanation of the actual mechanism that achieves the postulated equality between demand and supply,  but a possible explanation was put forward by Marshall's French contemporary, Léon Walras.  Walras described a market in which an imaginary auctioneer  invites offers to sell and offers to buy at an arbitrary starting price, and then announces a succession of  price revisions that  bring the amounts offered by buyers and sellers progressively closer together  until equality is reached - and allows no transactions to take place until that price is established <ref> Léon Walras ''Elements of Pure Economics'' (translated by William Jaffe from the 1874 original) Routledge 2007</ref>. Similar arrangements (termed "French auctions") are, in fact,  used to set opening prices in some stock markets, but the Walrassian auction was intended - and is widely accepted - as an analogy to be applied to markets in general.
The original theory of supply and demand  offered no explanation of the actual mechanism that achieves the postulated equality between demand and supply,  but a possible explanation was put forward by Marshall's French contemporary, Léon Walras.  Walras described a market in which an imaginary auctioneer  invites offers to sell and offers to buy at an arbitrary starting price, and then announces a succession of  price revisions that  bring the amounts offered by buyers and sellers progressively closer together  until equality is reached - and allows no transactions to take place until that price is established <ref> Léon Walras ''Elements of Pure Economics'' (translated by William Jaffe from the 1874 original) Routledge 2007</ref>. Similar arrangements (termed "[[French auction]]s") are, in fact,  used to set opening prices in some stock markets, but the Walrassian auction was intended - and is widely accepted - as an analogy to be applied to markets in general. It can be shown, however, that analogy is strictly applicable only to markets consisting of rational participants, each of whom is fully informed about the product and its substitutes,  each of whom acts independently in the exclusive pursuit of self-interest, and in which all transactions are costlessly enforceable. Those restrictions exclude the possibility of [[Externality|externalities]], of the exercise of [[market power]], of the existence of [[incomplete contracts]] and of their consequent costs.
<ref>[http://www.questia.com/read/105454747?title=The%20Economics%20of%20Contracts%3A%20%20Theories%20and%20Applications. For an account of the implications of incomplete  contracts, see Eric Brousseau and Jean-Michel Glachant  (eds):    ''The Economics of Contracts: Theories and Applications''.  Chapter 4,  Cambridge University Press, 2002] </ref>, and of all forms of cooperation or of motivations based upon social interaction.
<ref>[http://www.santafe.edu/~bowles/2000QJE.pdf For a survey of the implications of the assumptions underlying the Walrassian auctioneer model see  Samuel Bowles and Hubert Gintis: "Walrasian Economics in Retrospect", ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'' November  2000]</ref>


===Equilibrium===
===Equilibrium and disequilibrium ===
The term "[[equilibrium (economics)|equilibrium]]" is applied by economists to the situation in which supply is equal to demand - by analogy with the state of a physical body which is at rest because it is  acted upon by forces that are in balance.  It can also be seen as an optimum situation for each participant in a market given the reactions of the other participants - mirroring the games theory concept of a [[Nash equilibrium]].


===Disequilibrium===
Marshall's analysis of supply and demand was concerned with equilibrium in the market for a single product, taking no account of interactions with other markets - an approach that is termed termed "partial equilibrium analysis". By contrast, the term "general equilibrium analysis" describes an approach that takes account of such interactions - acknowledging, for example the interactions that take place between the market for steel with the market for iron ore and the interactions of that market with  the markets for ore-bearing land, mining machinery and so on. At the operational level, economists developing [[economic forecasting model]]s have used limited forms of general equilibrium analysis, and at the theoretical level, other economists have explored the characteristic of a closed system of interacting competitive markets. The "''Walras' law'' of markets" has established the possibility of simultaneous equilibrium of all of the markets in such a system and the Arrow-Debreu theorems <ref>Kenneth  Arrow and Gerard  Debreu: "The Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy", ''Econometrica'', vol. XXII 1954 </ref> <ref> Kenneth Arrow: "An Extension of the Basic Theorem of Classical Welfare Economics", '' Proceedings of the Second Berkeley Seminar on Mathematical Statistics and Probability'' University of California Press 1951</ref> have further developed the characteristics of completely general equilibrium.


In the absence of a Walrasian auctioneer, however, information failures may lead to disequilibrium as demands arise of which suppliers are unaware, and vice versa. Errors in forecasting traffic demand, could, for example, lead to an under-supply of transport services that - despite any pricing response - could persist for many years. Lack of price flexibility can also lead to disequilibrium, as  in the Keynesian account of the causes of unemployment <ref> See the article on [[macroeconomics]]</ref>. It is in fact, the problem of unemployment that has been the main reason for the study of the economics of disequilibrium, and economists including Axel Leijonhufvud and Edmond Malinvaud
<ref>[http://www.nbs.sk/BIATEC/BIA08_03/28_31.PDF, Edmond Malinvaud in ''Profiles of World Economists'' Národná Banka Slovenska 2008]</ref> have used the concept to provide alternative explanations of the mechanism of unemployment.


==Empirical evidence==
==Empirical evidence==
The theory that has been outlined depends entirely upon logical deduction from untested axioms, and it consequently  has limited application to the real world unless it is supplemented by empirical  evidence. Developments over the past 40 years in the field of [[experimental economics]] have, in fact, led to the creation of  a substantial body of evidence concerning human behaviour in trading situations. Experiments conducted by [[Vernon Smith]] have demonstrated that  equilibrium can be achieved in many situations without the necessity for [[perfect information]] or the conditions necessary for [[pure competition]]<ref> [http://www.econlib.org/library/Downloads/y2007/Smithexperimental.mp3  Vernon Smith (oral interview) :  ''Markets and Experimental Economics'',  on Econtalk .com,  Library of Economics and Liberty,  May 21 2007. ]</ref><ref>[http://www.econlib.org/Library/Columns/CourseyVSmith.html Don Coursey: ''Vernon Smith, Economic Experiments and the Visible Hand'',  Library of Economics and Liberty, October 2002]</ref>. The evidence indicates that market behaviour is strongly influenced  by the rules of the institutions within which the trading takes place, and has provided practical guidance concerning the efficient design of such institutions.


==References==
{{reflist}}


==References==
[[Category:Suggestion Bot Tag]]
<references/>

Latest revision as of 16:00, 23 October 2024

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Because of their importance to the development of economic theory, an appreciation of the concepts of supply and demand is essential to the understanding of economic theory. This article seeks to explain their significance in non-technical terms and to provide a simple introduction to the law of supply and demand, with links to more detailed explanations.

Definitions of the terms used in the article that are shown in italics can be found on the Related Articles subpage, and a selection of the diagrams and mathematical equations that are conventionally used for teaching purposes can be found on the Tutorials subpage.

Origins and applications

The proposition that prices are determined by supply and demand is so familiar that it seems like a statement of the obvious. In fact, it was not generally accepted, even by eminent intellectuals such as Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill and David Ricardo, until the idea was popularised by Alfred Marshall towards the end of the nineteenth century.[1] [2] Since then there has been general acceptance of the proposition that demand rises in response to a reduction in price, that supply rises in response to an increase in price, and that price somehow settles to a level where demand is equal to supply. That proposition has come to be been termed "the law of supply and demand" and is often thought to be as firmly established as the law of gravity. In fact it is what Marshall termed "a statement of a tendency", depending upon particular premises about human behaviour, and some economists have questioned its logical consistency [3]. It has nevertheless survived in general use as a robust statement that reflects widespread experience. In economics, it has served as a tool that has been used in the construction of other theories, and it has generated a terminology that has been widely used in discussions among economists.

Demand

Price effects

The basic premise that economists adopt when discussing demand was stated by Marshall as the proposition that "the larger the amount of a thing that a person has, the less ... will be the price which he will pay for a little more of it" - a proposition that they referred to as the law of diminishing marginal utility. That premise has detailed implications for the price/demand relationship that are discussed on the Tutorials subpage, but the only implication that is necessary to the operation of the law of supply and demand is that demand rises in response to a reduction in price and vice versa.

Among exceptions to this generally-observed behaviour are goods that people prize just because they are expensive - sometimes referred to as Veblen goods in reference to the economist Thorstein Veblen who coined the phrase "conspicuous consumption".

An increase (or decrease) in the price charged for a product usually has two effects: - one is to cause consumers to switch their buying from (or to) it, to (or from) other products; and the other is to bring about a reduction (or increase) in consumers' incomes with the consequences described in the following paragraph. Those two consequences of a price change are termed the substitution effect and the income effect. (In this context "substitution" refers to a switch to or from any other product. The particular effects of substitutes that serve as functional alternatives are described in a later paragraph). From a supplier's viewpoint, however, the relevant characteristic of the relationship between price and demand is the percentage increase of demand for a product that would result from a small percentage reduction in its existing price - a quantity known as the price elasticity of demand for the product.

Income effects

The missing passage in the above quotation from Marshall's Principles of Economics was his "other things being equal" qualification; and income is one of the other things that have to be taken into account. The effect of a rise in a community's income must obviously be a proportionately equal increase in its total spending, assuming no change in the proportion that it saves. That implies a community-wide income elasticity of demand of exactly one - but, within that average, different values pertain to different categories of product. It is common experience for example, that people spend a diminishing proportion on food as their incomes rise (an observation that is sometimes referred to as Engel's Law). There are circumstances in which Engel's law can have significant consequences. In international trade, its effect is a continuing deterioration in the terms of trade of food-exporting countries with every rise in the prosperity of their customer countries; and in some developing countries the income effect referred to in the previous paragraph can produce an exception to the law of supply and demand that is similar to that of Veblen goods, but for a different reason. In markets predominated by people whose income is spent mainly on a basic good such as rice, the income effect of a reduction in its price can lead them to spend less upon it, thus reversing the normal effect of a price reduction. (Goods to which this exception applies are termed Giffen goods). Corresponding to Engel's law at the other end of the spectrum, the income elasticity of demand of luxury goods such as sports cars and jewelery is usually well above one.

Demand with substitutes and complements

The demand for a product is reduced if a new substitute becomes available - as happened to CDs when DVDs became available - and is increased if the price of an existing substitute is increased. The converse applies to complementary goods, so that the demand for microwave ovens is increased by the introduction of improved microwaveable meals, and the demand for cars is reduced if the price of petrol is increased. The sensitivity of the demand for a product to a change in the price of a substitute or a complement is referred to as the cross elasticity of demand between the products, and is positive for substitutes and negative for complementary goods. However, in estimating the net effect upon demand of any price change, allowance has also to be taken of its effect upon consumers' incomes.

Supply

The production function

The price necessary to generate a particular supply of a product is taken to be that which is "just sufficient to induce capitalists to invest their capital, and workers of all grades to invest their personal capital" [4]. For the price to increase with increasing supply implies a production function for which every increase of output requires an increasing quantity of inputs - conforming, that is to say, to the "law of diminishing returns". In the alternative case of constant returns, price is determined solely by the cost of production [5].

Market interactions

The Auctioneer analogy

The original theory of supply and demand offered no explanation of the actual mechanism that achieves the postulated equality between demand and supply, but a possible explanation was put forward by Marshall's French contemporary, Léon Walras. Walras described a market in which an imaginary auctioneer invites offers to sell and offers to buy at an arbitrary starting price, and then announces a succession of price revisions that bring the amounts offered by buyers and sellers progressively closer together until equality is reached - and allows no transactions to take place until that price is established [6]. Similar arrangements (termed "French auctions") are, in fact, used to set opening prices in some stock markets, but the Walrassian auction was intended - and is widely accepted - as an analogy to be applied to markets in general. It can be shown, however, that analogy is strictly applicable only to markets consisting of rational participants, each of whom is fully informed about the product and its substitutes, each of whom acts independently in the exclusive pursuit of self-interest, and in which all transactions are costlessly enforceable. Those restrictions exclude the possibility of externalities, of the exercise of market power, of the existence of incomplete contracts and of their consequent costs. [7], and of all forms of cooperation or of motivations based upon social interaction. [8]

Equilibrium and disequilibrium

The term "equilibrium" is applied by economists to the situation in which supply is equal to demand - by analogy with the state of a physical body which is at rest because it is acted upon by forces that are in balance. It can also be seen as an optimum situation for each participant in a market given the reactions of the other participants - mirroring the games theory concept of a Nash equilibrium.

Marshall's analysis of supply and demand was concerned with equilibrium in the market for a single product, taking no account of interactions with other markets - an approach that is termed termed "partial equilibrium analysis". By contrast, the term "general equilibrium analysis" describes an approach that takes account of such interactions - acknowledging, for example the interactions that take place between the market for steel with the market for iron ore and the interactions of that market with the markets for ore-bearing land, mining machinery and so on. At the operational level, economists developing economic forecasting models have used limited forms of general equilibrium analysis, and at the theoretical level, other economists have explored the characteristic of a closed system of interacting competitive markets. The "Walras' law of markets" has established the possibility of simultaneous equilibrium of all of the markets in such a system and the Arrow-Debreu theorems [9] [10] have further developed the characteristics of completely general equilibrium.

In the absence of a Walrasian auctioneer, however, information failures may lead to disequilibrium as demands arise of which suppliers are unaware, and vice versa. Errors in forecasting traffic demand, could, for example, lead to an under-supply of transport services that - despite any pricing response - could persist for many years. Lack of price flexibility can also lead to disequilibrium, as in the Keynesian account of the causes of unemployment [11]. It is in fact, the problem of unemployment that has been the main reason for the study of the economics of disequilibrium, and economists including Axel Leijonhufvud and Edmond Malinvaud [12] have used the concept to provide alternative explanations of the mechanism of unemployment.

Empirical evidence

The theory that has been outlined depends entirely upon logical deduction from untested axioms, and it consequently has limited application to the real world unless it is supplemented by empirical evidence. Developments over the past 40 years in the field of experimental economics have, in fact, led to the creation of a substantial body of evidence concerning human behaviour in trading situations. Experiments conducted by Vernon Smith have demonstrated that equilibrium can be achieved in many situations without the necessity for perfect information or the conditions necessary for pure competition[13][14]. The evidence indicates that market behaviour is strongly influenced by the rules of the institutions within which the trading takes place, and has provided practical guidance concerning the efficient design of such institutions.

References

  1. Alfred Marshall Principles of Economics Book V Macmillan 1964
  2. For previous beliefs, see the article on history of economic thought
  3. For an account of some accusations of inconsistency, see the tutorials subpage of this article
  4. Alfred Marshall: Principles of Economics, p497,
  5. Alfred Marshall Principles of Economics Book V Chapter III, Macmillan 1964
  6. Léon Walras Elements of Pure Economics (translated by William Jaffe from the 1874 original) Routledge 2007
  7. For an account of the implications of incomplete contracts, see Eric Brousseau and Jean-Michel Glachant (eds): The Economics of Contracts: Theories and Applications. Chapter 4, Cambridge University Press, 2002
  8. For a survey of the implications of the assumptions underlying the Walrassian auctioneer model see Samuel Bowles and Hubert Gintis: "Walrasian Economics in Retrospect", Quarterly Journal of Economics November 2000
  9. Kenneth Arrow and Gerard Debreu: "The Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy", Econometrica, vol. XXII 1954
  10. Kenneth Arrow: "An Extension of the Basic Theorem of Classical Welfare Economics", Proceedings of the Second Berkeley Seminar on Mathematical Statistics and Probability University of California Press 1951
  11. See the article on macroeconomics
  12. Edmond Malinvaud in Profiles of World Economists Národná Banka Slovenska 2008
  13. Vernon Smith (oral interview) : Markets and Experimental Economics, on Econtalk .com, Library of Economics and Liberty, May 21 2007.
  14. Don Coursey: Vernon Smith, Economic Experiments and the Visible Hand, Library of Economics and Liberty, October 2002