Unemployment: Difference between revisions
imported>Nick Gardner |
imported>Nick Gardner |
||
Line 36: | Line 36: | ||
"purge the rottenness out of the system"<ref>[http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2007/11/07/purging-the-rottenness/ Paul Kugman: ''The Conscience of a Liberal'', New York Times November 7 2007]</ref>. | "purge the rottenness out of the system"<ref>[http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2007/11/07/purging-the-rottenness/ Paul Kugman: ''The Conscience of a Liberal'', New York Times November 7 2007]</ref>. | ||
In the course of the 1940s, however, most economists came to accept the contention of [[John Maynard Keynes]] that there could be involuntary unemployment - which, he argued<ref name=K>[http://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/ John Maynard Keynes: ''The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money'', eBooks@Adelaide, 2010]</ref>, results from a general fall in demand, brought about by an excess of planned savings over planned investment. | In the course of the 1940s, however, most economists came to accept the contention of [[John Maynard Keynes]] that there could be involuntary unemployment - which, he argued<ref name=K>[http://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/ John Maynard Keynes: ''The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money'', eBooks@Adelaide, 2010]</ref>, results from a general fall in demand, brought about by an excess of planned savings over planned investment. As interpteted by his [[Keynsians|"Keynesian"]] followers, [[Keynesian theory]] became the consensus explanation of unemployment, which was virtually unchallenged until [[Milton Friedman]] put forward a rival explanation. Friedman's contention was that temporary - and often protracted - increases above what he termed the [[natural rate of unemployment]] were the result of the impact of unanticipated changes in nominal demand on product and labour markets created by [[shock (economics)|shocks]] to the economy that could come from a variety of sources <ref>[http://web.cenet.org.cn/upfile/90714.pdf Milton Friedman: ''Inflation and Unemployment'', Nobel Memorial Lecture, December 13, 1976]</ref>. | ||
<!-- | <!-- | ||
<ref> page xxx of Keynes' ''General Theory''[http://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/ ]</ref> | <ref> page xxx of Keynes' ''General Theory''[http://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/ ]</ref> | ||
Line 46: | Line 46: | ||
the extent of competition or monopoly, the barriers or encouragements to | the extent of competition or monopoly, the barriers or encouragements to | ||
working in various occupations, and so on. | working in various occupations, and so on. | ||
--> | --> | ||
==Policy responses== | ==Policy responses== |
Revision as of 16:40, 22 August 2010
Because of its traumatic effects on those who experience it, unemployment is a matter of widespread concern. Its causes and consequences have been topics of investigation and of controversy in economics, and in psychology and sociology. On some occasions its limitation has been made a policy objective, and on others it has been used as an instrument of policy. Its harm can be mitigated but there is no prospect of its elimination.
Terminology
Economics textbooks sometimes refer to four categories of unemployment:
- frictional unemployment, which happens to people who leave one job to search for another;
- structural unemployment, which happens to people whose skills are no longer needed because of changes in technology or industry structure;
- wage-rigidity-, or classical, unemployment, which happens when wages are maintained at a level at which the demand for labour falls short of its supply; and
- demand-deficient-, or Keynesian, unemployment, which occurs in a recession when the demand for labour falls short of its supply for macroeconomic reasons.
None of those categories of unemployment can be defined with any precision for statistical purposes, and the term unemployment can itself be defined for those purposes only by drawing some arbitrary distinctions between unemployment and other forms of under-utilisation of labour. International and national statistical definitions have been published, all of which leave some scope for subjective interpretation.
The unemployment rate is the amount of unemployment expressed as a percentage of the labour force.
A discouraged worker is one who has stopped searching for suitable work because he believes that none is available.
The term full employment is usually defined as a situation in which the number of vacancies exceeds the number unemployed, but it may alternatively be taken to mean the absence of unemployment other than frictional and structural unemployment.
The term natural rate of unemployment usually means the same as non-accelerating-inflation rate of unemployment, but it is sometimes used to mean the unemployment rate that rules when the growth rate of the economy is in line with its long-term rate.
The effects of unemployment
The existence of unemployment signifies a loss of potential output and of incomes, but there are indications that its psychological damage may be more important. Recent survey evidence indicates that German workers value the psychological cost of unemploment at as much as three times the associated loss of income[1]. Fear of unemployment is also psychologically harmful, even to the extent of being an important predictor of psychological symptoms[2]. The loss of employment by family wage earners has been found to be particularly burdensome because it cuts deeply into their sense of obligation, their identity, and their status; and unemployment after marriage has been found to increase the incidence of divorce. [3]. The duration of unemployment has a significant influence: Americans who are unemployed for more than six months have been found to be much more likely to experience daily negative emotions, including worry, sadness, and stress and somewhat less likely to report positive emotions, such as happiness, than are those who are unemployed for a shorter time [4]. It has also been found that unemployed British men are less healthy, and have higher mortality rates, than are employed men [5].
The history of unemployment
Pre-war experience
The earliest well-documented accounts of mass unemployment concern the Great Depression of the 1930s[6] - (the human consequences of which are graphically depicted in John Steibeck's "Grapes of Wrath"[7]). The numerical records of unemployment for that period are based upon administrative records, on the basis of which it has been estimated that 25 per cent of all United States workers - including 37 per cent of its nonfarm workers - became unemployed [8]. Numerical estimates of 19th century mass unemployment are not available but it must be assumed to have been commonplace then, in view of the many recessions that occurred in the United States [9] and elsewhere. Earlier occurrences have also been reported, going back to the 16th century [10] and before.
Recent trends
There were no recorded instances of post-war unemployment until the oil crisis of 1973 - which was followed by a series of recessions that continued through the 1980s and 1990s. Databases of unemployment statistics trace the patterns of unemployed rates by age, gender, age and duration over the past 30 years. Differences among national definitions and collection methods make international comparisons hazardous, but approximate comparisons between internationally harmonised rates[11] are also available. During that period annual unemployment rates in the larger developed economies have topped 10 per cent during recessions and have usually averaged between 3 and 8 per cent in other years. Annual rates as low as 2 per cent have occurred in Japan and Sweden [12], but have seldom fallen below 3 per cent elsewhere. Youth unemployment rates of over 15 per cent, and sometimes as high as 30 percent, have occurred in developed economies during recessions, and have typically been 2½ to 4 times the average rate for all ages[13]. The percentage of the unemployed that have been out of work for at least a year during the period 2005/8 has varied from around 10 per cent in the united States to over 50 per cent in Germany[14]
The causes of unemployment
According to the prewar consensus, all unemployment (other than frictional unemployment) is voluntary - resulting from refusal to accept employment at the reduced rates of pay that are presumed to be available during recessions[15]. Recessions were themselves deemed to be instruments of progress: for example the Harvard economist, Joseph Schumpeter, advised that "depressions are not simply evils,... but forms of something which has to be done, namely, adjustment to change." [16], and United States Treasury Secretary, Andrew Mellon, told President Hoover that they serve to "purge the rottenness out of the system"[17].
In the course of the 1940s, however, most economists came to accept the contention of John Maynard Keynes that there could be involuntary unemployment - which, he argued[18], results from a general fall in demand, brought about by an excess of planned savings over planned investment. As interpteted by his "Keynesian" followers, Keynesian theory became the consensus explanation of unemployment, which was virtually unchallenged until Milton Friedman put forward a rival explanation. Friedman's contention was that temporary - and often protracted - increases above what he termed the natural rate of unemployment were the result of the impact of unanticipated changes in nominal demand on product and labour markets created by shocks to the economy that could come from a variety of sources [19].
Policy responses
Notes and references
- ↑ Andreas Knabe and Steffen Raetze: Quantifying the Non-Pecuniary Costs of Unemployment: The Role of Permanent Income, FEMM Working Paper No. 12/2007, April 2007
- ↑ Catherine Marsh and Carolyn Vogler (eds): Social Change and the Experience of Unemployment pp191-212, Oxford University Press 1994 [1](Questia subscribers)
- ↑ Cristobal Young: Unemployment, Income, and Subjective Well-Being: Non-Pecuniary Costs of Unemployment, allacademic, October 2007
- ↑ Jenny Marlar: Worry, Sadness, Stress Increase With Length of Unemployment, Gallup, June 2010
- ↑ Danny Dorling: Unemployment and Health, British Medical Journal, 10 March 2009
- ↑ Russell Freedman Children of the Great Depression, Houghton Mifflin Harcourt, 2005
- ↑ John Steinbeck: The Grapes of Wrath, Viking Press, 1939
- ↑ Gene Smiley: Great Depression, Library of Economics and Liberty
- ↑ US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2010
- ↑ R. H. Tawney: The Agrarian Problem in the Sixteenth Century, Longmans, Green 1912
- ↑ ILO Comparable Estimates, International Labour Office, 2010]
- ↑ International Labor Comparisons, United States Bureau of Labour Statistics, 2010
- ↑ Youth unemployment, ratio of youth unemp. rate to adult unemployment rate, by sex (ILO est./MDG), UNdata, The United Nations]
- ↑ Long-term unemployment (% of total unemployment), World Bank, 2009
- ↑ Arthur Pigou: The Theory of Unemployment, London: Macmillan 1933.
- ↑ Joseph A. Schumpeter, Essays on Entrepreneurs, Innovations, Business Cycles, and the Evolution of Capitalism (Transaction Publishers, 1989), 117.
- ↑ Paul Kugman: The Conscience of a Liberal, New York Times November 7 2007
- ↑ John Maynard Keynes: The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, eBooks@Adelaide, 2010
- ↑ Milton Friedman: Inflation and Unemployment, Nobel Memorial Lecture, December 13, 1976