Fiscal policy/Tutorials: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
(preliminary transfer fom national debt)
imported>Meg Taylor
No edit summary
 
(76 intermediate revisions by one other user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{subpages}}
{{subpages}}
==Fiscal sustainability==
==Fiscal stability==
====Overview====
The concept of [[fiscal sustainability]] is often used in discussing [[fiscal policy]] but it is absence is not directly observable. [[Fiscal instability]], on the other hand, can be observed from the conduct of the [[CDS]] and [[bond]] markets. It is possible, moreover, that a fiscal stance which  might otherwise be considered  to be sustainable, may develop fiscal instability because of the development of [[debt intolerance]]  toward the government in question that had arisen from [[herding (banking)|herding]] behaviour in the bond market. Thus the avoidance of fiscal instability would appear to be the more pressing - and possibly more demanding - policy objective.


====Overview====
===Sustainability and stability===
The ultimate limit upon the size of the national debt is reached when more money is required for its repayment than the government can raise from taxation - at which point,  the only alternative to a default amounting to national bankruptcy is repayment with money created for the purpose by the central bank <ref>For an account of the process by which a central bank can create money, see the tutorials subpage of the article on banking [http://en.citizendium.org/wiki/Banking/Tutorials]</ref>Money creation aside, national bankruptcy is, in factan inevitable long-term outcome if national debt persistently grows faster than gdp. That is known as the ''debt trap'', and its avoidance is the economic policy objective known as "fiscal sustainability". Fiscal sustainability normally<ref> Assuming that the interest paid on government bonds is greater than the gdp growth rate.</ref>  requires the maintenance of a surplus  of  tax revenue over public expenditure, when averaged over a period of five to ten years, and the   average size of that surplus, when expressed as fraction of the national debt,  has to be at least equal to the difference between the interest rate payable and the gdp growth rate<ref> According to the "fiscal sustainability identity", which is examined on the [[/Tutorials|tutorials subpage]] and at page 315 of Frederic Fourie: ''How to Think and Reason in Macroeconomics''. JUTA 2001</ref>.
====Sustainability====
If the annual interest payable  on a government's debt rise faster than the national income, the point will eventually be reached at which they could would exceed the revenue that could be raised by taxation. The [[Fiscal policy/Tutorials#The debt trap identity|debt trap identity]] establishes that the budget surplus (or reduced deficit) needed to avoid an increase in the ratio of debt to  GDP depends upon the level of that ratio and the difference between the interest rate  payable on the debt and the growth rate of nominal GDP.
 
===="Structural" deficits====
In  discussions of  the sustainability of the budget deficit during  a [[recession]],  an arbitrary distinction is often drawn between what are termed its "cyclical" and "structural" components. The cyclical component is defined for that purpose as that part of the  budget deficit that is attributable to a temporary departure of national output from its trend, and which ceases when trend output  growth resumes - and the structural component is defined as the remainder.  The distinction has the merit of isolating that part of the budget deficit that is relevant to the question of sustainability. However, a reliable estimate of the size of a structural deficit is not possible until some time after the recession in question is over. It usually differs from the country's pre-crisis deficit  as a result of loss of tax revenues from companies that fail during the crisis.  Its isolation during a recession depends upon  forecasts of unknowns, including the future trends of output and prices. Determination of the future trend of output  depends, in turn  upon estimates of the success of the investments corresponding to that part the deficit that complies with the [[Golden Rule (finance)|Golden Rule]].
 
====Fiscal instability====
An increase in the [[risk premium]] that the bond market applies to a government's borrowing may increase the cost of its borrowing to an extent that increases the market's perception of its riskiness, in response to which the bond market may apply a further increase in its risk premium. (An expectation of a reduction in economic growth could also  trigger such a response).  Repetition of that sequence could eventually force the government to default by placing the cost of a roll-over of maturing debt beyond its capacity to raise the necessary funds. The market's awareness of that possibility may add to the destabilising effect of its actions. Unlike sustainability, fiscal instability is an observable phenomenon.
 
==The fiscal dilemma==
Fiscal policy usually involves a choice between the objective of achieving economic growth and the need to avoid [[fiscal instability]]. That choice arises, in particularconcerning the conduct of  fiscal policy during a [[recession]]. The operation of [[automatic stabilisers]] during a [[recession]] necessarily increases a country's budget  deficit - sometimes to the extent of raising fears of fiscal instability. The choice has to be made between increasing the deficit further in order to mitigate the severity of the  recession, and reducing it in order to maintain investor confidence. That choice is complicated by the fact that, in the absence of effective action to counter the recession, its increasing severity might in any case raise the budget deficit to an extent that would cause a loss of confidence. The consensus policy choice before 2008 had been to refrain from fiscal expansion and to counter the recession solely by an expansionary [[monetary policy]]. But in face of the threat posed by the international [[crash of 2008]], most of the [[Group of Twenty|G20 governments]] considered it necessary to use discretionary fiscal policy to augment the diminishing effects of monetary expansion. The recession came to an end in 2009, but in view of the perceived fragility of the recovery, the dilemma remained: whether to implement immediate tax increases or public expenditure cuts, or to postpone such action pending signs of a sufficiently robust recovery (without which the economy's [[automatic stabilisers]] could ensure a continuing increase in the [[budget deficit]].
 
A fiscal dilemma also arises at times of economic stability. A [[structural deficit]] that is devoted entirely to [[self-financing government investment]] is, by definition, sustainable. The use for that purpose  of voluntary borrowing rather than compulsory taxation must be presumed to increase growth in view of the [[Taxation#Aggregate effects|growth-reducing effects of taxation]]. The dilemma is whether - and how far - to sacrifice some growth prospects by limiting  deficit-financed investment  in order to maintain sufficient unused capacity to borrow in order to mitigate the effects of a [[recession]] or other emergencies. Perceptions of the prospects and severity of such emergencies may be expected to influence the judgement that is made, and an upward revision of those perceptions may be expected to follow a severe recession.
 
<!--
Until the [[Great Recession]] developing countries the . [[Debt intolerance]]<ref>[http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/13398/1/MPRA_paper_13398.pdf, Carmen Reinhart: ''Debt intolerance: Executive summary'', Munich Personal RePEc Archive, 2004]</ref> among investors  and anticipations of default by speculators had been such a frequent  cause of [[sovereign default]] among them that the [[International Monetary Fund]] had  made its assistance conditional upon  the avoidance of deficits, even during recessions<ref>[http://www.econ.utah.edu/activities/papers/2004_09.pdf Alcino  Câmara and Neto Vernengo: ''Fiscal Policy and the Washington Consensus: A Post Keynesian Perspective'', Working Paper No: 2004-09, University of Utah Department of Economics, 2004]</ref>).
-->
 
<!--
==The cyclical and structural components of public debt==
The concept of a "[[structural deficit]]" is sometimes  introduced to distinguish the discretionary component of a country's deficit from the larger component which arises during a recession from the operation of its [[automatic stabilisers]].  


Although that identity-based criterion would ensure fiscal sustainability in a stable, risk-free environment, it is generally accepted that a more stringent criterion is needed in order to guard against operating risks. A government's ability to market bonds  offering any  particular rate of return depends upon the willingness of operators in the bond market to accept that rate of return, and that willingness is influenced by market  expectations.  A comparatively recent development is the availability of ''credit default swaps'' that enable market operators to insure against the risk of ''sovereign default''.  Operators in the bond market may be expected to require an increase in the rate of return on a government's bonds sufficient to offset the premium (or ''sovereign spread''} on such insurance. Sovereign spreads tend to be greater, the greater the level of national debt as a percentage of gdp, but they are also influenced by  expectations of increases in that level, and by other factors, including expectations of gdp growth or decline.  Most of the sovereign defaults of recent years have been due to banking and currency crises rather than to a previously excessive level of public debt<ref>[http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/0xx/doc18/Genacct.pdf Bianca di Paoli and Glen Hoggart: ''The Costs of Sovereign Default'', Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin]</ref>


That  term  can simply  be defined as a deficit that is unsustainable. To avoid that circularity, however, an unsustainable deficit can more usefully be defined as that part of a [[cyclically-adjusted budget deficit]] that is not self-financing (by definition, a self-financing investment does not increase long-run public expenditure). In principal, however,  the concept of  self-financing publicly financed  investment should extend,  beyond investments that produce short-term accounting returns, to include those government-financed investments that  yield  increases in [[human capital]] or [[social capital]] that are self-financing in the longer term. Since there is always some uncertainty about the gains from such investments, the estimation of the size of the structural deficit (or surplus) necessarily involves the use of subjective judgement.
-->


===The debt trap identity===
==The debt trap identity==


According to the debt trap identity, the annual increase in public debt as a percentage of GDP is given by:
According to the debt trap identity (proved  below), the increase, Δd, in [[national debt]] in any given year, as a percentage of [[Gross Domestic Product|GDP]] is given by:


:::::: Δd  =  f + d(r - g)
:::::: Δd  =  f + d(r - g)


where d is public debt as a percentage of GDP<br> and f is the primary budget deficit (shown with a negative negative sign if a surplus)  as a percentage of GDP,<br> and r is the interest rate payable on government debt.
where d is the amount of the accumulated debt as a percentage of GDP at the beginning of the year, <br> and f is the [[primary budget balance|primary budget deficit (or surplus)]] for the year (shown with a negative negative sign if a surplus)  as a percentage of GDP,<br> r is the interest rate payable on the debt, <br> and g is the then current nominal GDP growth rate.
 
So that if Δd = 0


:''(for proof of the identity, see paragraph 2 of the addendum subpage[http://en.citizendium.org/wiki/National_Debt/Addendum])''
::::::: f = -d(r - g)


===Sustainability===
- which is to say that to avoid an increase in public debt in the course of any year, the budget deficit during that year must not be greater than the opening level of debt  multiplied by the difference between the interest rate on the debt and the GDP growth rate in that year (and that means a budget surplus if the interest rate is greater than the growth rate).


A necessary  condition for long-term sustainability is that Δd does not consistently  exceed zero - since otherwise the interest due would eventually amount to a greater percentage of GDP than could conceivably be financed from taxation. The dept trap, implies, thereforethat <br>
If, for example, r were 5% and g were 2% then a debt of 50% of gdp would require a surplus of 1.5% of GDP, a debt of 100% of GDP would require a surplus of 3% of gdp,  and so forth.
-&nbsp; &nbsp;if the interest rate is greater than the growth rate, sustainability requires an average  budget surplus ratio equal to at least d(r-g) and <br>
-&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;if the growth rate exceeds the interest rate, it requires that the budget deficit ratio does not on average exceed d(g-r).


However, the identity embodies the implicit assumptions  that deficits earn no return, and that they do not affect  growth rates or interest rates.
(Proof:-
<small>
Let D and Y be the levels of public debt and GDP at the beginning of a year; and,<br> let F be the primary, or discretionary budget deficit (the total deficit excluding interest payments) and,<br> let r be the annual rate of interest payable on the public debt; <br>and assume that&nbsp; F, r, and g are all mutually independent.


Since many diferent combinations of r, g are possible the debt trap identity does not define a unique relation between the the debt/gdp ratio, d and the minimum value of surplus/gdp (or maximum value of the deficit/gdp) ratio, f that is necessary for sustainability, even under the assumptions that have been implicitly adopted.
- then the public debt at the end of the year is&nbsp; D<sub>1</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;D&nbsp;+&nbsp;F&nbsp;+Dr; the GDP at the end of the year is &nbsp; Y<sub>1</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;Y(1&nbsp;+&nbsp;g); <br>and the ratio of public debt to GDP has risen from &nbsp;D/Y&nbsp;to&nbsp; (D&nbsp;+&nbsp;F&nbsp;+&nbsp;Dr)/{Y(1&nbsp;+&nbsp;g);


Some light can nevertheless be thrown on the issues by inserting some typical values for r and g and by qualifying the implicit assumptions.
- thus the increase in the ratio of public debt to GDP in the course of a year is:


Interest rates on government bonds are usually greater than gdp growth rates, so an average budget surplus will usually be required  for sustainability. <br> If, for example, r were 5% and g were 2% then - on the original assumptions -  a debt of 50% of gdp would require an average surplus of 1.5% of gdp a debt of 100% of gdp would require an average  surplus of 3% of gdp, and so forth.
:::Δ(D/Y)&nbsp;=&nbsp;(D&nbsp;+&nbsp;F&nbsp;+&nbsp;Dr)/{Y(1&nbsp;+&nbsp;g)}&nbsp;-&nbsp;D/Y
Let&nbsp;1/{Y(1;+&nbsp;g)}&nbsp;=&nbsp;A &nbsp;andso that AY = 1/(1&nbsp;+&nbsp;g)&nbsp;,and&nbsp; 1/AY&nbsp;=&nbsp;1&nbsp;+&nbsp;g
&nbsp;<br>
- then:<br>
:::Δ(D/Y)&nbsp;=&nbsp;A(D&nbsp;+&nbsp;F&nbsp;+&nbsp;Dr)&nbsp;-&nbsp;D/Y
::::=&nbsp;&nbsp;A(&nbsp;D&nbsp;+&nbsp;F&nbsp;+&nbsp;Dr&nbsp;&nbsp;-&nbsp;D/AY)
- and substituting&nbsp;1&nbsp;+&nbsp;g&nbsp;for&nbsp;1/AY:
::::=&nbsp;&nbsp;A(&nbsp;D&nbsp;+&nbsp;F&nbsp;+&nbsp;Dr&nbsp;-&nbsp;D&nbsp;-&nbsp;Dg)
substituting for A:
:::Δ(D/Y)&nbsp;=&nbsp;{F&nbsp;+&nbsp;D(r&nbsp;-&nbsp;g)}/{Y(1&nbsp;+&nbsp;g)}
or, approximately:-
:::Δ(D/Y)&nbsp;=&nbsp;{F&nbsp;+&nbsp;D(r&nbsp;-&nbsp;g)}/Y
::::=&nbsp;F/Y&nbsp;+&nbsp;(r&nbsp;-&nbsp;g)D/Y
Let &nbsp;f&nbsp;=&nbsp;F/Y&nbsp;,and&nbsp;d&nbsp;=&nbsp;D/Y<br>


The first qualification to those conclusions is that a deficit devoted  exclusively to  investments having  positive net present values in financial terms would eventually, by definition, be  self-financing and would therefore not require a surplus for sustainability. That means that the debt trap applies only to that part of the debt that is undertaken for other reasons. This qualification is important because failure to take up successful investment opportunities  in order to reduce the national debt imposes an opportunity cost on future generations.
- then&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp; &nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;Δd&nbsp;&nbsp;=&nbsp;&nbsp;f&nbsp;+&nbsp;d(r&nbsp;-&nbsp;g)


The second qualification concerns the possibility the growth rate, g, could be influenced by  a deficit. At times of impending recession any avoidance of a drop in growth that could be achieved by a deficit would at least partially offset the increase in surplus that would subsequently be necessary for sustainability. (It could conceivably even reduce the required surplus. If, for example, an increase in the debt ratio from 50% to  100% averted the replacement of a 2% growth rate by a 2% rate of decline and the interest rate remained at 5%, it would reduce the required surplus from 3.5% to 3%.)
where f is the primary budget deficit as a percentage of GDP, and d is public debt as a percentage of GDP)


A third qualification is that r may not be independent of d.  The size of the public debt may influence the interest rate that would have to be paid on it. That can happen if operators in the market for government bonds believe that there is an increased probability of default, in which case they will require a risk premium in addition to the rate of return that they would otherwise require. The size of the premium is indicated by the country's ''sovereign spread''.
</small>


Lastly, it may be necessary to take account of expectations, both rational and irrational. A rationally-formed expectation of a reduction in g may increase the market value of r because of its effect upon default risk. More importantly,  a rumour of increased default risk may be self-fulfilling because of ''herding'' behaviour in the bond market.
==Notes and references==
{{reflist}}

Latest revision as of 02:17, 27 October 2013

This article is developing and not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
Addendum [?]
 
Tutorials relating to the topic of Fiscal policy.

Fiscal stability

Overview

The concept of fiscal sustainability is often used in discussing fiscal policy but it is absence is not directly observable. Fiscal instability, on the other hand, can be observed from the conduct of the CDS and bond markets. It is possible, moreover, that a fiscal stance which might otherwise be considered to be sustainable, may develop fiscal instability because of the development of debt intolerance toward the government in question that had arisen from herding behaviour in the bond market. Thus the avoidance of fiscal instability would appear to be the more pressing - and possibly more demanding - policy objective.

Sustainability and stability

Sustainability

If the annual interest payable on a government's debt rise faster than the national income, the point will eventually be reached at which they could would exceed the revenue that could be raised by taxation. The debt trap identity establishes that the budget surplus (or reduced deficit) needed to avoid an increase in the ratio of debt to GDP depends upon the level of that ratio and the difference between the interest rate payable on the debt and the growth rate of nominal GDP.

"Structural" deficits

In discussions of the sustainability of the budget deficit during a recession, an arbitrary distinction is often drawn between what are termed its "cyclical" and "structural" components. The cyclical component is defined for that purpose as that part of the budget deficit that is attributable to a temporary departure of national output from its trend, and which ceases when trend output growth resumes - and the structural component is defined as the remainder. The distinction has the merit of isolating that part of the budget deficit that is relevant to the question of sustainability. However, a reliable estimate of the size of a structural deficit is not possible until some time after the recession in question is over. It usually differs from the country's pre-crisis deficit as a result of loss of tax revenues from companies that fail during the crisis. Its isolation during a recession depends upon forecasts of unknowns, including the future trends of output and prices. Determination of the future trend of output depends, in turn upon estimates of the success of the investments corresponding to that part the deficit that complies with the Golden Rule.

Fiscal instability

An increase in the risk premium that the bond market applies to a government's borrowing may increase the cost of its borrowing to an extent that increases the market's perception of its riskiness, in response to which the bond market may apply a further increase in its risk premium. (An expectation of a reduction in economic growth could also trigger such a response). Repetition of that sequence could eventually force the government to default by placing the cost of a roll-over of maturing debt beyond its capacity to raise the necessary funds. The market's awareness of that possibility may add to the destabilising effect of its actions. Unlike sustainability, fiscal instability is an observable phenomenon.

The fiscal dilemma

Fiscal policy usually involves a choice between the objective of achieving economic growth and the need to avoid fiscal instability. That choice arises, in particular, concerning the conduct of fiscal policy during a recession. The operation of automatic stabilisers during a recession necessarily increases a country's budget deficit - sometimes to the extent of raising fears of fiscal instability. The choice has to be made between increasing the deficit further in order to mitigate the severity of the recession, and reducing it in order to maintain investor confidence. That choice is complicated by the fact that, in the absence of effective action to counter the recession, its increasing severity might in any case raise the budget deficit to an extent that would cause a loss of confidence. The consensus policy choice before 2008 had been to refrain from fiscal expansion and to counter the recession solely by an expansionary monetary policy. But in face of the threat posed by the international crash of 2008, most of the G20 governments considered it necessary to use discretionary fiscal policy to augment the diminishing effects of monetary expansion. The recession came to an end in 2009, but in view of the perceived fragility of the recovery, the dilemma remained: whether to implement immediate tax increases or public expenditure cuts, or to postpone such action pending signs of a sufficiently robust recovery (without which the economy's automatic stabilisers could ensure a continuing increase in the budget deficit.

A fiscal dilemma also arises at times of economic stability. A structural deficit that is devoted entirely to self-financing government investment is, by definition, sustainable. The use for that purpose of voluntary borrowing rather than compulsory taxation must be presumed to increase growth in view of the growth-reducing effects of taxation. The dilemma is whether - and how far - to sacrifice some growth prospects by limiting deficit-financed investment in order to maintain sufficient unused capacity to borrow in order to mitigate the effects of a recession or other emergencies. Perceptions of the prospects and severity of such emergencies may be expected to influence the judgement that is made, and an upward revision of those perceptions may be expected to follow a severe recession.


The debt trap identity

According to the debt trap identity (proved below), the increase, Δd, in national debt in any given year, as a percentage of GDP is given by:

Δd = f + d(r - g)

where d is the amount of the accumulated debt as a percentage of GDP at the beginning of the year,
and f is the primary budget deficit (or surplus) for the year (shown with a negative negative sign if a surplus) as a percentage of GDP,
r is the interest rate payable on the debt,
and g is the then current nominal GDP growth rate.

So that if Δd = 0

f = -d(r - g)

- which is to say that to avoid an increase in public debt in the course of any year, the budget deficit during that year must not be greater than the opening level of debt multiplied by the difference between the interest rate on the debt and the GDP growth rate in that year (and that means a budget surplus if the interest rate is greater than the growth rate).

If, for example, r were 5% and g were 2% then a debt of 50% of gdp would require a surplus of 1.5% of GDP, a debt of 100% of GDP would require a surplus of 3% of gdp, and so forth.

(Proof:- Let D and Y be the levels of public debt and GDP at the beginning of a year; and,
let F be the primary, or discretionary budget deficit (the total deficit excluding interest payments) and,
let r be the annual rate of interest payable on the public debt;
and assume that  F, r, and g are all mutually independent.

- then the public debt at the end of the year is  D1 = D + F +Dr; the GDP at the end of the year is   Y1 = Y(1 + g);
and the ratio of public debt to GDP has risen from  D/Y to  (D + F + Dr)/{Y(1 + g);

- thus the increase in the ratio of public debt to GDP in the course of a year is:

Δ(D/Y) = (D + F + Dr)/{Y(1 + g)} - D/Y

Let 1/{Y(1;+ g)} = A  andso that AY = 1/(1 + g) ,and  1/AY = 1 + g  
- then:

Δ(D/Y) = A(D + F + Dr) - D/Y
=  A( D + F + Dr  - D/AY)

- and substituting 1 + g for 1/AY:

=  A( D + F + Dr - D - Dg)

substituting for A:

Δ(D/Y) = {F + D(r - g)}/{Y(1 + g)}

or, approximately:-

Δ(D/Y) = {F + D(r - g)}/Y
= F/Y + (r - g)D/Y

Let  f = F/Y ,and d = D/Y

- then                 Δd  =  f + d(r - g)

where f is the primary budget deficit as a percentage of GDP, and d is public debt as a percentage of GDP)

Notes and references