Bank failures and rescues: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
No edit summary
Line 11: Line 11:
===The vulnerability of banks===
===The vulnerability of banks===


The fact that banks often lend as much as twenty times the value of their  share capital makes their continued solvency sensitive to defaults on those loans. "Retail banks", that obtain funds from depositors,  are also vulnerable to the risk that fears of ''insolvency'' can result in  "bank ''runs''". They are also vulnerable to the "''contagion''"  that can occur when depositor "''herding''" converts the  news of a run on one of their number into  runs on the others. "Wholesale" or "investment" banks, that obtain their funds by borrowing on the "''money markets''" and the "''interbank markets''", can also suffer from contagion resulting from herding by market operators.  Before the adoption by ''central banks'' of the roles of "''lenders of last resort''",  herding and contagion were believed to have  led to the failure of many otherwise solvent banks. The pre-war creation  of the Federal Reserve Bank as lender of last resort did not eliminate contagion in US banking in the inter-war years, but there is evidence to suggest that it was no longer common <ref> A study of the 1932 Chicago banking crisis indicated that riskiness of assets distinguished failed banks from survivors, suggesting an absence of contagion. [http://www.nber.org/papers/w4934 Charles . Calomiris and  Joseph  Mason: , ''Contagion and Bank Failures During the Great Depression: The June 1932 Chicago Banking Panic'',  NBER Working Paper No. 4934  November 1994]</ref>. However, the development in the latter  years of the twentieth century of  complex systems of "''securitisation''", added progressively to their  vulnerability to contagion  by making the banks a component of a complex, tightly-coupled  interactive, financial  system; and by adding to the difficulty of assessing risks. That development led to the word-wide incidence  of 0 banking  crises that have been termed "''systemic''" on a World Bank database because they were so extensive that they threatened the integrity of their national financial systems <ref> World Bank researchers have listed 117 systemic crises [http://www1.worldbank.org/finance/html/database_sfd.html ''Bank Crises Database'' World Bank 2003]</ref>, a growing number of which had been contagious in the sense of spreading into neighbouring countries.  The culmination of that trend was the world-wide  [[crash of 2008]].
The fact that banks often lend as much as twenty times the value of their  share capital makes their continued solvency sensitive to defaults on those loans. "Retail banks", that obtain funds from depositors,  are also vulnerable to the risk that fears of ''insolvency'' can result in  "bank ''runs''". They are also vulnerable to the "''contagion''"  that can occur when depositor "''herding''" converts the  news of a run on one of their number into  runs on the others. "Wholesale" or "investment" banks, that obtain their funds by borrowing on the "''money markets''" and the "''interbank markets''", can also suffer from contagion resulting from herding by market operators.  Before the adoption by ''central banks'' of the roles of "''lenders of last resort''",  herding and contagion were believed to have  led to the failure of many otherwise solvent banks. The pre-war creation  of the Federal Reserve Bank as lender of last resort did not eliminate contagion in US banking in the inter-war years, but there is evidence to suggest that it was no longer common <ref> A study of the 1932 Chicago banking crisis indicated that riskiness of assets distinguished failed banks from survivors, suggesting an absence of contagion. [http://www.nber.org/papers/w4934 Charles . Calomiris and  Joseph  Mason: , ''Contagion and Bank Failures During the Great Depression: The June 1932 Chicago Banking Panic'',  NBER Working Paper No. 4934  November 1994]</ref>. However, the development in the latter  years of the twentieth century of  complex systems of "''securitisation''", added progressively to their  vulnerability to contagion  by making the banks a component of a complex, tightly-coupled  interactive, financial  system; and by adding to the difficulty of assessing risks. That development led to the word-wide incidence  of banking  crises that have been termed "''systemic''" on a World Bank database because they were so extensive that they threatened the integrity of their national financial systems <ref> World Bank researchers have listed 117 systemic crises [http://www1.worldbank.org/finance/html/database_sfd.html ''Bank Crises Database'' World Bank 2003]</ref>, a growing number of which had been contagious in the sense of spreading into neighbouring countries.  The culmination of that trend was the world-wide  [[crash of 2008]].


===The case for rescues===
===The case for rescues===
There are cogent arguments for not rescuing failing banks. In the first place a rescue could hamper the normal competitive process by which failures are replaced by more efficient competitors and secondly, its precedent creates a ''moral hazard'' by motivating banks to increase their profitability by taking otherwise unwarrantable risks. The contrary argument came to light in  1866 when contagion from the collapse of the English  Gurney-Overend bank    led to the collapse of over 200 companies <ref>[http://www.ehs.org.uk/ehs/conference2003/assets/Taylor.doc  James Taylor  ‘’Limited Liability on Trial: the Commercial Crisis of 1866 and its Aftermath’’ Economic History Society Conference 2003]</ref>. The influential commentator Walter Bagehot  urged that in a future panic the Bank of England  should "advance freely and vigorously to the public out of its reserves"<ref>[http://www.questia.com/read/106768931# Walter Bagehot: ''Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market'' Scribner, Armstrong, 1874]</ref>, and in 1890 the Bank rescued the failing Barings bank by guaranteeing loans to it by other banks. A similar conclusion by the United States authorities led to the creation of the [[Federal Reserve System]] with powers to act as ''lender of last resort''. Those measures were designed to  prevent failures caused by contagion, and they were not intended to prevent failures that were the direct result of insolvency. In time, however, it came to be recognised that some financial organisations had become "too big to fail" because their failure would endanger too large a proportion of the financial system. In the late twentieth century, after there had been several cases of international contagion there were even proposals to turn the [[International Monetary Fund]] into an international lender of last resort
There are cogent arguments for not rescuing failing banks. In the first place a rescue could hamper the normal competitive process by which failures are replaced by more efficient competitors and secondly, its precedent creates a ''moral hazard'' by motivating banks to increase their profitability by taking otherwise unwarrantable risks. The contrary argument came to light in  1866 when contagion from the collapse of the English  Gurney-Overend bank    led to the collapse of over 200 companies <ref>[http://www.ehs.org.uk/ehs/conference2003/assets/Taylor.doc  James Taylor  ‘’Limited Liability on Trial: the Commercial Crisis of 1866 and its Aftermath’’ Economic History Society Conference 2003]</ref>. The influential commentator Walter Bagehot  urged that in a future panic the Bank of England  should "advance freely and vigorously to the public out of its reserves"<ref>[http://www.questia.com/read/106768931# Walter Bagehot: ''Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market'' Scribner, Armstrong, 1874]</ref>, and in 1890 the Bank rescued the failing Barings bank by guaranteeing loans to it by other banks. A similar conclusion by the United States authorities led to the creation of the [[Federal Reserve System]] with powers to act as ''lender of last resort''. Those measures were designed to  prevent failures caused by contagion, and they were not intended to prevent failures that were the direct result of insolvency. In time, however, it came to be recognised that some financial organisations had become "too big to fail" because their failure would endanger too large a proportion of the financial system. In the late twentieth century, after there had been several cases of international contagion there were even proposals to turn the [[International Monetary Fund]] into an international lender of last resort
<ref>[http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/1999/010399.HTM  Stanley Fischer ''On the Need for an International  Lender of Last Resort.'' International Monetary Fund 1999]</ref>.
<ref>[http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/1999/010399.HTM  Stanley Fischer ''On the Need for an International  Lender of Last Resort.'' International Monetary Fund 1999]</ref>.
Thus the rescue decision depends upon the often difficult task of balancing its exchequer cost against the possibility of a systemic crisis that could cost a substantial proportion of a year's national income <ref>The average loss of national output from 33 systemic losses has been estimated as 25% of GDP [http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/fsr/2003/fsr15art6.pdf]</ref> - and taking account of the danger that measures to avert an immediate crisis might increase the long-term likelhood of another. The outcome suggests that mistakes were often made.
(Decisions concerning regulatory measures that could reduce the need for rescues are dicussed in the artivle on [[banking]])


==The treatment of banking crises==
==The treatment of banking crises==
Line 21: Line 26:
The proliferation of banking crises during the last two decades of the twentieth century led to the development of a variety of  preventative and corrective measures <ref>[http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/fsr/2003/fsr15art6.pdf Glen Hoggart and Jack Reidhill: ''Resolution of Banking Crises: a Review'', Bank of England Financial Stability Review: December 2003 ]</ref>. The preventative measures included schemes to insure depositors against loss and the designation of selected organisations as  TBTF (too big to fail). Corrective measures taken at the early stages of an incipient systemic failure have included government promotion of  the takeover of failing banks by stronger survivors , but action in response to a fully-developed systemic crisis has usually taken the form of injections of capital or  the acquisition of equity by government agencies.
The proliferation of banking crises during the last two decades of the twentieth century led to the development of a variety of  preventative and corrective measures <ref>[http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/fsr/2003/fsr15art6.pdf Glen Hoggart and Jack Reidhill: ''Resolution of Banking Crises: a Review'', Bank of England Financial Stability Review: December 2003 ]</ref>. The preventative measures included schemes to insure depositors against loss and the designation of selected organisations as  TBTF (too big to fail). Corrective measures taken at the early stages of an incipient systemic failure have included government promotion of  the takeover of failing banks by stronger survivors , but action in response to a fully-developed systemic crisis has usually taken the form of injections of capital or  the acquisition of equity by government agencies.


<ref>The average loss of national output from 33 systemic losses has been estimated as 25% 0f GDP [http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/fsr/2003/fsr15art6.pdf]</ref>


==The inter-war years==
==The inter-war years==

Revision as of 08:25, 21 October 2008

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Timelines [?]
Addendum [?]
Glossary [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Many of the numerous bank failures that have occurred over the years have not proved harmful to their national economies. Governments have found it necessary, however, to guard against the danger of "systemic failure" resulting from a general loss of confidence in the banking system and have, from time to time, rescued a failing bank in order to avert that danger. There have nevertheless been several instances of banking crises that have done serious damage to national economies.

For definitions of the terms shown in italics in this article, see the glossary.
For a detailed list of failures and rescues in their historical sequence, see the timelines subpage.

Background

The vulnerability of banks

The fact that banks often lend as much as twenty times the value of their share capital makes their continued solvency sensitive to defaults on those loans. "Retail banks", that obtain funds from depositors, are also vulnerable to the risk that fears of insolvency can result in "bank runs". They are also vulnerable to the "contagion" that can occur when depositor "herding" converts the news of a run on one of their number into runs on the others. "Wholesale" or "investment" banks, that obtain their funds by borrowing on the "money markets" and the "interbank markets", can also suffer from contagion resulting from herding by market operators. Before the adoption by central banks of the roles of "lenders of last resort", herding and contagion were believed to have led to the failure of many otherwise solvent banks. The pre-war creation of the Federal Reserve Bank as lender of last resort did not eliminate contagion in US banking in the inter-war years, but there is evidence to suggest that it was no longer common [1]. However, the development in the latter years of the twentieth century of complex systems of "securitisation", added progressively to their vulnerability to contagion by making the banks a component of a complex, tightly-coupled interactive, financial system; and by adding to the difficulty of assessing risks. That development led to the word-wide incidence of banking crises that have been termed "systemic" on a World Bank database because they were so extensive that they threatened the integrity of their national financial systems [2], a growing number of which had been contagious in the sense of spreading into neighbouring countries. The culmination of that trend was the world-wide crash of 2008.

The case for rescues

There are cogent arguments for not rescuing failing banks. In the first place a rescue could hamper the normal competitive process by which failures are replaced by more efficient competitors and secondly, its precedent creates a moral hazard by motivating banks to increase their profitability by taking otherwise unwarrantable risks. The contrary argument came to light in 1866 when contagion from the collapse of the English Gurney-Overend bank led to the collapse of over 200 companies [3]. The influential commentator Walter Bagehot urged that in a future panic the Bank of England should "advance freely and vigorously to the public out of its reserves"[4], and in 1890 the Bank rescued the failing Barings bank by guaranteeing loans to it by other banks. A similar conclusion by the United States authorities led to the creation of the Federal Reserve System with powers to act as lender of last resort. Those measures were designed to prevent failures caused by contagion, and they were not intended to prevent failures that were the direct result of insolvency. In time, however, it came to be recognised that some financial organisations had become "too big to fail" because their failure would endanger too large a proportion of the financial system. In the late twentieth century, after there had been several cases of international contagion there were even proposals to turn the International Monetary Fund into an international lender of last resort [5].

Thus the rescue decision depends upon the often difficult task of balancing its exchequer cost against the possibility of a systemic crisis that could cost a substantial proportion of a year's national income [6] - and taking account of the danger that measures to avert an immediate crisis might increase the long-term likelhood of another. The outcome suggests that mistakes were often made.

(Decisions concerning regulatory measures that could reduce the need for rescues are dicussed in the artivle on banking)


The treatment of banking crises

The proliferation of banking crises during the last two decades of the twentieth century led to the development of a variety of preventative and corrective measures [7]. The preventative measures included schemes to insure depositors against loss and the designation of selected organisations as TBTF (too big to fail). Corrective measures taken at the early stages of an incipient systemic failure have included government promotion of the takeover of failing banks by stronger survivors , but action in response to a fully-developed systemic crisis has usually taken the form of injections of capital or the acquisition of equity by government agencies.


The inter-war years

The United States

In the immediate post-war years there was a rapid growth in the number of United States banks, and there were relatively few failures. In 1921, however, there was a surge in the number of bank failures, especially in farming areas, and the number of banks started to decline. In 1930, a massive further increase in failures occurred in response to the Great Recession, and failures continued at a high level until the "banking holiday" of 1933. The introduction in that year of the Federal Deposit Insurance scheme restored investors' confidence, and there were few failures during the remainder of the inter-war period.

Post-war developments

1940 to 2007

2007/2008

References